Over the last two decades, and especially in the last few years, land regularization and upgrading programs have been implemented in informal settlements by central, regional and local governments in several Latin American countries. Important lessons must be learned from this incipient practice of urban policy making, not only to contribute toward improving existing experiences, but also to guide those governments that are confronting the phenomenon for the first time, or more likely are confronting the need to design policies to deal with significant increases in informal urban development.
To address this need, the Lincoln Institute sponsored its third offering of the course Informal Markets and Land Regularization Programs in Urban Areas, in November 2003. It was held in Recife, Brazil because of the city’s historic tradition of urban policy making, including its regularization program (PREZEIS), which for the past 20 years has been a pioneering instrument, despite its many shortcomings. The course brought together about 35 people with varied academic backgrounds and institutional positions representing 10 Latin American countries: Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela.
The 13 intertwined lessons offered here draw on the papers presented in Recife and on experiences discussed in the two previous courses in 2001 and 2002, as well as ideas generated in the meeting of the Institute’s Latin American Network on Land Regularization in Brasília, Brazil, in July 2003. This brief, critical analysis of land regularization programs reflects contributions from many people, but the authors take full responsibility for any misrepresentations that a general synthesis like this one may produce (see Figure 1).
1. The Process of Favelización
The process of informal production of urban space is increasing at a significant pace in Latin America, despite the fact that, unlike Africa and Asia, the region has been solidly urbanized for many decades. Occupied areas are becoming denser, and new settlements are being formed daily. Increasingly, these occupations encroach on environmentally sensitive areas, near protected water reservoirs, on public land, and in other areas not suitable for human occupation or economically feasible in the formal land market. This process has created all sorts of harmful repercussions—socio-environmental, legal, economic, political and cultural—not only for the millions of residents living in informal settlements, but also for city governments and the entire urban population. Despite the many regularization and upgrading programs implemented in the last few decades, the development rate of new informal settlements has been twice and even three times that of urban population growth. Thus, increasing informality is not exclusively the result of demographic change or even the increase in urban poverty, which also has been growing but at a much lower rate.
2. The Vicious Cycle of Informality
Multiple factors are responsible for the establishment of informal settlements. Over and above demographics and macroeconomic factors affecting urban poverty (employment and income policies), local variables contribute to the “unexplained variance” of increasing informality. By acting or failing to act, local authorities have fomented the growth of the phenomenon through exclusionary land use regulation, favoring wealthy neighborhoods in the spatial allocation of public investments, outright complicity with the delinquent practices of land subdividers, and inadequate local fiscal policies.
The corollary of this tolerance of informality is of great importance for land pricing policy. The informal market values and benefits from greater regulatory freedom and from the social values associated with traditional networks among residents within the settlements. Both of these dynamics affect prices in the informal market, which are reaching absurd levels. For example, a 6-square-meter (60-square-foot) wooden shack on a mangrove swamp in Recife has been valued at US$1,300. Such extremes and variations in prices reflect the diversity of informal processes at work in the access to urban land and housing, both among different settlements and within each settlement. Attacking the factors responsible for the vicious cycle of price formation should be an indispensable ingredient of any policy seeking to mitigate the consequences of informality.
3. A World of Diversity
Far from being a homogeneous phenomenon, informality manifests itself in many forms, contexts and places. Enormous differences may be found within and between settlements in the same city, not to mention among cities within a country and among cities in different countries. Each informal area has good and bad neighborhoods; relatively high-valued and low-valued areas; an uneven distribution of whatever services are available; and properties with different types of tenure rights. The income levels of many families in informal areas also are variable and in some cases are well above those of families in formal areas who are typically expected to pay for certain publicly provided services and benefits.
In comparing the archipelago of informal settlements distributed within formal neighborhoods in Latin America, property price gradients have been found to be uncorrelated, revealing altogether different market forces. Although both formal and informal areas are subject to vigorous land markets, the intervening price determinants are of different orders of magnitude. As mentioned above, regulatory freedoms, as well as longstanding informal networks that support the exchange of intangible benefits, affect property values. These realities must be taken into account when designing regularization programs that can offer positive reform of traditional practices.
There is also a need to adjust the programs to the different conditions of newly occupied areas and long-established settlements in consolidated areas. A clearer chain of market transactions can be traced in the newer occupations, whereas there is usually no linear succession of transactions in older areas. Furthermore, established settlements reflect a complex overlay of informally defined rights and transactions, such as rooftops sold to a third party as buildable “land,” which in turn may give rise to an additional living space. It is by no means clear whether regularization programs should start with recent occupations, where the costs of upgrading are lower and degrees of freedom are greater, or with older, consolidated areas that present more pressing social consequences, but where some legal rights may already exist.
4. Tolerance of Informality
Despite all the negative implications, public authorities have tolerated informal urban development processes, whether because of neglect, political convenience, ambiguous actions or even direct promotion of informal occupations. There is, however, little understanding that such tolerance generates rights over time and little information about the extremely high costs, both absolute and relative, of what is involved in upgrading programs. At the same time, tolerance of informal occupations is accompanied by a growing acceptance by both public authorities and public opinion that consolidated settlements should be upgraded with services, equipment and infrastructure. A recent study conducted by Cities Alliance in Brazil shows that the decision to regularize an irregular settlement is often made more quickly than the decision to approve a new regular settlement (six months versus two or three years).
This official tolerance also applies to the acceptance of “second-class solutions” for “second-class citizens” and often results in the early deterioration of upgraded areas. The combination of poor-quality materials and low-cost, unconventional techniques used in upgraded areas, as well as greater pressure on the existing infrastructure because of increased densification, renders the infrastructure obsolete and incurs high maintenance costs. Moreover, upgraded areas usually are not properly integrated into the municipal fiscal system. Throughout the region, the fiscal irresponsibility of municipal administrators is aggravated further by their failure to take responsibility for the broader scope of territorial development, as well as for their negligence or at best paternalistic attitude toward these regularized settlements.
5. Expectations and Land Values
Regularization programs to date have addressed a very small percentage of existing informal settlements, and as a result the vast majority of people living informally have not benefited from any type of public intervention. Furthermore, many regularization programs have been formulated without a proper understanding of the causes of informality, and they often deliver counterproductive results that contribute to the process of increasing socio-spatial segregation.
The mere expectation of upgrading puts a premium value on the land designated for improvements, thus significantly impacting prices in the informal market. The higher the expectation that an area will be regularized in the future, the higher the premium on that land and the higher the market demand for lower-priced subdivisions elsewhere. This suggests two approaches to upgrading: comprehensive programs for everyone in a few places coordinated with policies to change future expectations about cost recovery schemes; or partial upgrading in all informal areas of the city so expectations about market activity will be more balanced and consistent. The importance of integrating upgraded areas into municipal fiscal systems is not yet properly understood.
6. Isolated and Fragmented Policies
Public intervention in informal settlements through regularization programs has been promoted in an isolated, sectoral way without the necessary integration between such programs and the wider context of urban land management policies that have a direct bearing on such settlements. These policies include construction of social housing; rehabilitation of dilapidated urban centers; occupation of vacant areas and buildings; broader spatial allocation of public investments in urban infrastructure and services; modernization of tax collections and cadastres; and public-private partnerships. Moreover, most regularization programs have been limited to residential areas and have rarely been extended to informal industrial and commercial businesses, vacant public buildings and land in central areas, or informal settlements in rural areas.
At all levels of government, regularization programs have been marked by structural fragmentation— within programs, between secretariats and ministries, and among national, state and local levels—and as a result existing resources are often misspent or fail to reach all intended beneficiaries. The programs also have suffered from a lack of administrative continuity due mostly to changes in local political contexts. Rather than supplementing other initiatives, regularization programs often absorb much of the (limited) financial capacity of local municipalities, causing other social housing programs to be sacrificed or neglected. This problem has its origins in both the broad credit lines opened by national and international multilateral agencies and the absence of a requirement that local administrations match the financial burden of the program with efforts to expand their own revenue sources. In general, credit lines for regularization programs have been established without careful consideration of the financial capabilities of municipalities.
7. Lack of Financial Resources
As if the above problems were not enough, regularization programs have not been supported by adequate financial resources. The budgetary provisions are not compatible with the proposed and sometimes ambitious objectives, and often there are no specific funds for the programs. Revenues resulting from urban planning operations (such as earmarking resources from the sale of building rights in formal and high-income areas) have not been properly used to support upgrading. Resources from international agencies have been poorly spent, especially because there has not been a rigorous evaluation of the programs, nor a firm demand that their targets or objectives are fully accomplished. In addition, there are no adequate micro-credit policies in place to support or encourage community organizations.
8. Dissociation Between Upgrading and Legalization
Although it could be argued that illegality is a consequence of the insufficient supply of serviced land at affordable prices, in the vast majority of regularization programs the greater emphasis on upgrading has been dissociated from housing improvement and socioeconomic programs aimed at integrating communities, as well as from specific policies to legalize areas and plots. The components of upgrading and legalization have been conceived as if they were separate processes, or, frequently, as if legalization were an automatic result of the upgrading process. Most upgrading programs seem to fall short of what is required for land occupations to be legalized in the first place. As a result, those few programs that have reached the legalization stage have had to invent legal-political solutions, which often do not reflect the urban conditions actually in force in the area.
Despite the publicity given to regularization programs, the number of titles that actually result in a document issued by the property registration office is disappointingly low. The complexities imposed by law and the resistance and conservative attitudes of notaries and registration offices have been identified as some of the most critical bottlenecks to overcome. It should be added that most families, once they receive a title recognizing their legitimate right to their property, simply do not bother to complete the registration process, often because they do not understand its legal overtones or because it is too expensive or cumbersome. This situation has led to an outcry for the simplification of titling and registration systems and an associated need to disempower the existing bureaucratic entities.
9.The Importance of Titling
Given these problems, few programs have reached the legalization stage, and even fewer have achieved the registration of legalized plots. Perhaps because of that failure, many analysts have come to believe that titles are not important, that the mere perception of security of tenure would suffice. Although it is true that such a perception is indeed the main factor that encourages people to start investing in their houses, titling is important for two reasons: the personal interests of the occupiers (security of tenure, protection against forced eviction, domestic conflicts, marital separation, inheritance, problems with neighbors, access to an address and to forms of credit); and the interest of the city as a whole, since legal titling can contribute to the stabilization of land markets and allow for more rational and better articulated forms of public intervention.
There is still great resistance to land titling programs, especially on the part of the judiciary and the general public. However, it is important to note that individual beneficiaries of titling programs often do not have a full understanding of the protections and limitations of their title—What is it good for? Why does one need to actually register the title? All this suggests that educational programs for both city officials and residents should accompany the introduction of any regularization programs.
In addition, there has been little reflection on the implications of the kinds of instruments used to legalize plots. The emphasis placed on individual freehold titles has ignored the need for collective legal solutions for collective social problems; whenever such legal instruments have been used, they have not been introduced in a way that renders the new legal order compatible with the existing urban order and with the legal implications of the instruments. Most existing legal options have not been fully explored and generally lack creativity. Moreover, a consistent effort has yet to be made to have the new legal instruments fully validated by credit agencies, and by society at large.
10. The Fallacy of Popular Participation
The political quality of regularization programs has varied enormously, but in general the processes of popular participation in formulating and implementing the programs have been of little significance. This situation has been further aggravated by the creation of artificial forms of participation as a result of demands from financing agencies. The designed mechanisms for popular participation are in general a sheer formality, if not a farce from the outset. Very few programs have assimilated solutions proposed by the affected community. The political-institutional and cultural framework within which most regularization programs have been formed, along with the constraints imposed by the way these programs are financed, virtually eliminates any room for a truly effective public role, since public participation normally implies major challenges to the status quo. Regularization programs are more often perceived as solutions from or for the establishment than as a response to the real needs of the majority of the low-income population.
11. Compatible Scale, Patterns and Rights
Perhaps the main problem with regularization programs is the difficulty in making the scale of the interventions compatible with the technical, urban and environmental patterns proposed for the settlements, as well as with the nature of the rights to be recognized for the occupiers. These factors of scale, patterns and rights have to be discussed together to guarantee the sustainability of the programs and their impact on reality.
12. The After-effects of Regularization Programs
After an area is upgraded or a settlement is legalized, the public authorities normally do not maintain their presence in the areas. They should perform many important functions, from monitoring and evaluating the maintenance of installed equipment (notably water and sewage systems) to creating new guidelines or rules governing new occupations. As a result of the absence of official oversight and intervention, many areas rapidly begin to deteriorate. Moreover, the legitimization provided by the regularization program may make neighboring (originally formal) areas more prone to being “contaminated” by new informal land use practices. In general, regularization programs have not led to the promised urban, social and cultural integration of upgraded areas, and the informal areas remain stigmatized as second-rate long after they have been upgraded. The idea that regularized areas are placed in a new, virtuous trajectory rarely survives beyond the original documents setting the justifications for the program.
13. Balancing Individual Freedoms and Public Functions
In spite of their concern with the need to guarantee that the beneficiaries of public intervention are indeed the occupiers of informal settlements, regularization programs have not met a proper balance between respect for individual rights and freedoms and the programs’ public functions (the recognition of the social right to housing and the need to set aside urban areas for that purpose). Frequently the adopted legal solutions embed restrictions intending to freeze the mobility process within the areas (affecting terms of sale, acquisition, rent and so forth), which only helps to generate more informality.
The strategy of focusing on an area or social group seems to ignore the very nature and origins of informality, which is in fact a Catch-22 situation. The lack of sufficient finances in most programs would, on one hand, suggest that beneficiaries should not be able to cash in their benefits and move on to a new informal occupation to be similarly regularized in the future. On the other hand, the cost of monitoring and controlling such practices may be too high, if not unfeasible. Restrictions on transactions would simply generate new kinds of informal arrangements.
Interestingly, very few regularization programs actually accommodate or adjust to the potential upward and downward mobility of the affected occupants. They are formulated with a static community in mind. Intra-urban mobility, particularly among informal settlements and between formal and informal areas, is not well understood and thus is largely ignored. A possible way out of this conundrum would be to establish a cost-recovery scheme or value capture mechanism at the very beginning of planning for a new regularization program.
Conclusion
Regularization programs are typically not formulated with well-defined goals and timetables, and the problem is made worse by the lack of suitable evaluation indicators. In short, the declared objectives of regularization programs in Latin America (promotion of security of tenure and socio-spatial integration) have not been translated into an adequate combination of a comprehensive diagnosis, effective instruments and a clear implementation strategy, not to mention deficiencies in management capacity. As a result, the Latin American experience with regularization so far can not be considered fully successful.
It may be said, however, that regularization programs have shown merit in raising public awareness about the legitimacy of claims for more effective and comprehensive responses to the needs of a significant and growing group of citizens now excluded from the formal socioeconomic system. These programs have enabled some of the urban poor to remain in central, serviced areas of Latin American cities and have improved the livelihood and conditions of those living in regularized settlements, notwithstanding this discussion of their shortcomings. Given the cruel dynamics of socio-spatial segregation in the region, this fact is in itself of great importance.
Edésio Fernandes is a part-time lecturer in the Development Planning Unit of University College London.
Martim O. Smolka is senior fellow and director of the Lincoln Institute’s Program on Latin America and the Caribbean.
Related Land Lines Articles
Angel, Shlomo, and Douglas Keare. 2002. Housing policy reform in global perspective. April: 8–11.
Calderon, Julio. 2002. The mystery of credit. April: 5–8.
Fernandes, Edésio. 2002. The influence of de Soto’s The Mystery of Capital. January: 5–8.
———. 2002. Faculty profile. July: 12–13.
Smolka, Martim O. 2003. Informality, urban poverty and land market prices. January: 4–7.
Smolka, Martim O., and Laura Mullahy. 2003. A decade of changes: A retrospective of the Latin America program. October: 8–12.
Figure 1:
Dos and Don’ts of Regularization Programs
Dos
Don’ts
The Lincoln Institute sponsored a wide-ranging international conference in June on “Land Policies for Urban Development.” A few of the major themes and messages from the presentations are summarized below.
The three most populous developing countries, China, India, and Indonesia, with 40 percent of the world’s population, are entering the stage of rapid urbanization simultaneously. By 2030, they are projected to add an additional 2.2 billion persons to urban areas, increasing the world’s urban population by nearly 80 percent over the 2000 figure of 2.8 billion. The related infrastructure investment needs are likely to reduce or eliminate any perceived savings surplus in the world. Economic growth and urbanization in most East Asian countries have occurred in coastal regions and near ports. In India, however, urbanization and growth are currently focused on inland cities and on information technology rather than on labor-intensive manufacturing. This may be due to weaknesses in traditional infrastructure services, particularly in transport.
A review of property tax practices across 25 countries found an extremely wide range of practices in terms of tax base definitions, tax rate levels, and assessment practices. In most developing countries property tax rates are very low (a fraction of one percent of market values). Nevertheless, property taxes are one of the few revenue sources under local control and are an important component of local government revenues. Simplicity was found to be a virtue of property tax regimes in developing countries, because complexity raises administrative costs and erodes public support for property taxes.
Efforts to measure land values in urban areas of the United States—either by analyzing vacant land sales or by subtracting the value of the structure from property sales—indicate that they have appreciated more rapidly than construction costs since 1985, with a 2005 value between $12 and $24 trillion. This compares to estimates for 1980 of about $3 trillion, suggesting that land values have increased four to eight times in a period when consumer prices have increased only 2.4 times. In addition, land values have been volatile, falling by around 40 percent from 1989 to 1995 in many urban markets before increasing rapidly in the past 10 years.
While average housing prices across the United States have increased faster than construction costs, increases in housing prices have been particularly sharp in urban areas on the West Coast and on the East Coast from the mid-Atlantic region to New England. In these coastal metropolitan areas, median single-family housing prices are nearly five times larger than median prices in the least expensive metropolitan areas in other regions.
Analysis across all U.S. metropolitan areas shows a strong association between the level of housing market regulation and the level of prices—metropolitan areas with the most regulations on residential development have the highest housing prices. Moreover, areas with the highest prices also have low growth rates of housing stocks. Together these findings suggest that rapid growth in housing prices in coastal cities is due in large part to growing impediments on the supply side of the market. Supply constraints may not be only a U.S. phenomenon. A review of planning experience in the United Kingdom showed that urban development corporations, which have the power to overrule local regulations, have been more effective than most other approaches in fostering urban revitalization.
The ownership of second homes (for own use, not for rent to others) has been growing rapidly in the United States, and about 5.6 percent of all U.S. housing units were second homes in 2004. The main determinants of second-home ownership are income, wealth, and age of the household head. Second-home ownership is highest for those in their sixties, suggesting that the aging of the baby boom generation will increase second-home ownership. Additional research (and better data) is required to determine if this trend is related to the location or characteristics of a household’s primary residence.
The complete collection of papers and commentaries presented at the conference will be published as an edited volume in 2007.
During the last decade, bus rapid transit (BRT) has revolutionized regional transportation planning in much of the developing and developed world. BRT went from being a fringe transportation option used in a handful of Brazilian and Australian cities to becoming a prominent mass transportation alternative for local and national governments.
Arguably the BRT concept with highest recognition is the provision of an exclusive right-of-way for bus transit coupled with high-frequency service. In South America, BRT systems in Curitiba, Brazil, and Bogotá, Colombia, feature networks of dedicated lanes designated for exclusive use by large-capacity, articulated buses, with expedited boarding and alighting.
The Latin America region faces formidable challenges in education and training on urban land policy, planning, and taxation issues. For nearly 20 years the Lincoln Institute has been offering programs on these topics in 17 countries in continental South America, and several others in the Caribbean. These countries have different legal frameworks (some unitary and others federal), approximately 400 subnational governments (states, provinces, departments), about 15,000 municipalities representing a wide range of local conditions, and more than 100,000 public officials responsible for land-related policies and management.
As part of the Department of International Studies, the Program on Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) identifies partners, convenes appropriate audiences, advises on strategy, promotes research, and develops materials for education and training on key topics related to land policy. These include mitigation of rampant informality, reinforcement of self-financing through land value increments resulting from local public investments recovery, improving the performance of the property tax, and impacts of public interventions.
To reach out to its diverse audience, the LAC Program has developed a wide range of in-person classroom courses, seminars, and conferences for practitioners, including legislative and executive policy officials and their senior technical staff, as well as scholars, university students, and citizens. Traditionally, most of these programs have been weeklong professional development courses, offered once a year to 30 to 50 international participants from multiple countries, or ad hoc international or national conferences designed for hundreds of participants. However, the diversity of the Latin America region precludes tailoring the in-person model for different jurisdictions, and limited resources often prevent public agencies and private institutions from being able to send their personnel to the large cities where the events normally occurred.
As the programs became better known and the number of public officials seeking to participate in them grew, the Institute had to reevaluate its strategic approach to its mandate to improve the quality of debate on land policy issues through educational programs. Thus, to complement continuing in-person programs for targeted audiences in specific cities and countries, in 2004 the LAC Program began to develop other educational formats and media to reach key policy makers and professionals in government and academic institutions who were interested in urban land policy issues but unable to participate in one-time events.
The still-evolving LAC distance education offerings (Educación a Distancia, EAD) encompass many alternative approaches, including self-paced online courses; moderated courses that incorporate multiple interactive media formats; and graduate-level courses in partnership with Latin American universities and other institutions. These courses use a variety of tools and materials, ranging from simple, downloadable written materials to multimedia platforms such as Moodle, Blackboard, and eTEACH.
Pedagogical Strategies
Beyond the technological solutions to disseminating educational materials, a pedagogical problem remained. The pedagogical strategy adopted by the LAC Program for distance education is represented by an inverted triangle (figure 1). Users can remain at the general level, taking self-paced courses to obtain cross-topical but somewhat basic knowledge, or they can go deeper in one topical area through moderated courses or specialized, graduate-level university programs.
Working closely with pedagogical experts and guided by the Lincoln Institute mandate, the LAC staff and adjunct faculty gradually developed an EAD model based on the principles of constructivism, a psychological theory of knowledge developed by Swiss developmental psychologist Jean Piaget, which argues that humans generate knowledge and meaning from their experiences. Constructivism can be considered in contrast to positivism, in which scientific knowledge comes from positive affirmation of theories through strict scientific methods, such as quantitative research. Given the diversity and complexity of the subjects involved in land policy, the LAC Program has explored both approaches in creating its distance education courses. In this context, constructivism applies more often to knowledge associated with policy alternatives, while positivism is used in more technical courses based on the application of tools.
The LAC Program organizes courses within the constructivist framework, encouraging a broad discussion about the issues related to urban land policy without preconceived notions. The distance education courses on the Moodle platform allow for the creation of virtual communities and wide-ranging discussion environments, with participants from many Latin American countries contributing concerns and experiences that may be quite different from those of the faculty. The LAC Program also offers courses that are instrumental to the development of quantitative and (geo)statistical tools used in urban land policy, in this case applying the principles of positivism and learning-by-doing.
Over the years, we have developed two products with different features, applications, and goals: restricted-access courses (moderated, graduate-level, and in-person support courses); and unrestricted, free-access, self-paced courses. All of these online courses are offered in Spanish for practitioners from public and private institutions involved in urban issues, and some materials are now being translated to and from Portuguese.
Moderated and Self-Paced Courses
Moderated courses were our first choice to address the challenges of informing and preparing public officials to expand the scope of their policy alternatives, because they provide a strong educational foundation based on readings, discussion, and reflection. All of our moderated courses are free; however, applicants are selected through a competitive application process. Classes have about 45 participants each, normally including at least one representative from each of the region’s countries. The courses are developed over nine weeks, each with a designated professor responsible for teaching and/or orienting participants; the third, fifth, and ninth weeks are available for students to complete or make up specific tasks or quizzes.
These courses are set up on the Moodle platform, which offers excellent results in terms of performance and usability. Three main tools are used.
Completion of tasks and quizzes along with participation in discussions constitute the minimum criteria for participants to pass the course and receive a certificate from the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
The LAC Program offers nine distance education courses with overlapping themes (figure 2). One set of courses includes Financing Cities with Urban Land, which fosters a critical examination of the various policies regarding the financing of cities through urban land; and Property Tax and Urban Financing, which provides the analysis of the legal, political, and economic principles of land taxation as a beneficial instrument for urban development. This tax course overlaps with two others: Application of Multipurpose Cadastres in Defining Urban Land Policies, which covers topics related to land tenure, geotechnologies and urban land valuation systems used in different Latin American jurisdictions; and Urban Land Valuation Techniques, which presents the techniques and basic principles of commercial valuations and mass appraisal of urban properties.
A second set of courses includes Legal Dimensions of Land Policy, which offers an analysis of the main approaches and categories found in urban legal systems in Latin America, with the review of relevant theoretical and practical aspects for urban public managers. It intersects with Management of Urban Land Markets, which provides an examination of the structure, function, and regulation of markets and their relationship to the economic, social, and environmental problems of cities.
The technical connections between the two sets are provided by two additional courses: Urban Land Markets Analysis Techniques, which analyzes the basic principles of land and real estate economics and the application of empirical methods; and GIS Applications for Urban Studies, which covers basic concepts of GIS, alphanumeric databases structure, and cartographic tools useful in urban studies. Most of these topics and techniques are covered transversally in the course on Land Policy Definition in Small Cities, introduced in Spring 2010.
Over the years, we have experimented with different configurations of faculty and administrative staff. Since 2009 we have implemented a simple but efficient coordinating structure with senior Lincoln Institute staff responsible for the strategic decisions in terms of courses and production of materials, and a distinguished group of adjunct professors and their assistants who communicate directly with the participants and follow up on instructions about uploading materials, assignments, and quizzes. To keep up with increasing topical diversity and enrollment demand for EAD courses, in 2010 we increased the number of faculty from 22 to 52 and developed a special course for all teachers and assistants to ensure that they are all operating at the same pace and within the same framework on distance education pedagogy and Moodle tools.
Another response to the consistent increase in demand has been the development of self-paced courses as an alternative and complement to the more intensive moderated courses. Using different platforms and multimedia materials, self-paced courses rely heavily on videos taped during in-person classes and available for viewing on the Lincoln Institute’s Web site. These products are also being adapted for free downloading, especially for use by private and nongovernmental institutions, small cities, and educational institutions.
Course Materials
LAC distance education courses are supported by both written and audiovisual materials. The written materials, usually in a PDF format, are selected for individual student reading, analysis, and reflection. They include documents authored by the participating professors, papers available on the Internet for public access, and chapters of books and reports published by the Lincoln Institute and other sources. For certain courses, legislation and public documents from various countries are shared in order to facilitate comparative case studies.
Some course materials, primarily those authored by course faculty, have been compiled as e-books that can be downloaded in whole or in part to meet the needs of the course participants. The four e-books produced to date (in Spanish or Portuguese) are also available to other interested users.
A variety of audiovisual materials provide additional information and enhance comprehension through different production and user technologies, but with the common goal of accelerating understanding of the core curriculum. Early multimedia offerings were simple videos of professors teaching a class with alternating PowerPoint slides to create the atmosphere of an in-person lecture. The videos are produced with high-quality digital technology, and are used for both self-paced and moderated courses. Some videos are filmed in a studio and others are filmed live during a scheduled course.
The incorporation of audio classes has further enhanced the distance education experience. Professors in countries throughout the region tape their voices using free software and following the instructions of the course administrators. The audio files and related PowerPoint slides are sent to the editing team, which then creates an audio class. The sound portions of the multimedia classes (both video and audio) are converted to MP3 audio files.
The audio and video classes are being transcribed for two purposes: to give the hearing or visually impaired access to the classes, and to create the basic material for translation and dubbing or subtitling. Moreover, transcriptions are used by faculty to write the chapters of the e-books that are being produced in collaboration with many of the courses. These resources inform the participants in moderated courses, and are also available to the general public on the Lincoln Institute Web site.
Working in distance education requires constant updating of information as land policy issues and contexts change, and the educational arena itself is expanding rapidly with new tools, methods, and strategies. Currently we are considering the implementation of a learning environment in Second Life, a leading alternative in cost-effective virtual education solutions for collaborative learning. Second Life simulates an academic environment with classrooms, meeting areas, libraries, and other resources. Participants create a virtual image of themselves (an avatar) that can be moved among these facilities to access bibliographic materials, attend classes, and interact with the avatars of other participants. At present, we are designing a virtual learning environment and preparing faculty to work in it, using their avatars for navigation.
Linking Distance and In-Person Education
By experimenting with various combinations of distance learning and in-person instruction, the LAC Program staff has learned that the mix is a promising and productive model to pursue. For several years, we have developed tailor-made moderated courses as prerequisites for in-person weeklong courses in Latin America. We are now beginning to use existing self-paced courses as a preparatory stage for participants as well. This allows us to make better use of classroom time and minimize the need for sessions designed to equalize participants’ understanding of concepts, terminology, and fundamentals during the weeklong professional development courses.
As an alternative to the nine-week courses, we have also developed partnerships with several universities and nongovernmental institutions to implement graduate-level courses that combine classroom instruction with distance education content. These courses rely on the same basic distance education infrastructure, professors, and materials used for the moderated courses. Most of them, after being implemented initially with Lincoln Institute support, continue being offered by the partner institutions themselves. Some of these courses were developed in the Dominican Republic and Bolivia, where the LAC Program had not previously worked, thus establishing partnerships that have led to sustained relationships.
This combination model began with several initiatives that brought together select groups of alumni from previous online courses, and it has continued as part of two specialization courses—Urban Planning and Financing, and Urban Cadastres and Land Valuation—both of which conclude their distance learning segments with weeklong, in-person sessions. Our partner institutions plan to offer the courses on a regular basis with continued Lincoln Institute support in the form of class materials and the distance education platform structure.
Achievements and Remaining Challenges
A number of initial challenges have been overcome and can now be described as successful outcomes of the LAC Program’s distance education initiative.
Despite these advances and experiences acquired over time, some challenges remain.
Final Considerations
The results achieved by the Lincoln Institute’s LAC Program over the past six years demonstrate that the distance education platform is both functional and reliable, and that a combination of online course types enables us to reach more people and places without losing contact or missing the daily monitoring of participants. The success of the current pilot programs has special significance because it confirms that distance education is a valid option for the Latin America region due to increasing availability of Internet access and the openness to alternative learning methods.
About the Author
Diego Alfonso Erba is a fellow in the LAC Program at the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and professor at Universidad Nacional de Rosario, Argentina. He is a land surveyor/engineer with doctoral and post-doctoral degrees in surveying sciences. He began working with distance education in Brazil in 2001 at Universidade do Vale do Rio dos Sinos (UNISINOS), and has spearheaded this program for the Lincoln Institute.
The current state of global urban development is unsettling and plagued with man-made and natural disasters. In many developing countries, the government does not have the fiscal and institutional capacity to build affordable housing and basic infrastructure for the growing urban population, resulting in a proliferation of informal settlements and slums. At the same time, natural disasters in some of these distressed regions have destroyed homes, roads, water and sewage systems, and other public facilities, exacerbating the already limited basic services available to the urban poor.
In response to these problems, many international aid agencies such as UN-HABITAT and the World Bank, as well as governments, scholars, and practitioners, are looking for new ideas or repackaging existing ways to rebuild cities. This article discusses a long-established land management tool that has attracted recent attention—land readjustment (LR)—and describes how selected elements of this tool are being adopted to assist post-earthquake reconstruction efforts in Chile.
The LR approach emphasizes the integration of the urban economy, city planning, law, and governance with land management to form a comprehensive urban development or upgrading strategy. It requires an interdisciplinary team of experts with different perspectives to work on a concrete land development project. Although many scholars such as Doebele (1982) and Hong and Needham (2007) have emphasized the importance of this integrated approach, some practitioners perceive it as merely a tool to facilitate land transactions. This narrow view has limited opportunities in some developing countries to resolve urban upgrading and development problems in a more comprehensive way.
The recent resurgence of interest in LR is due to the recognition of the importance of coordinating economic, legal, political, and social institutions in the design and implementation of urban (re)development plans. Practitioners are also contemplating the possibility of extending LR from management of peri-urbanization and post-disaster reconstruction to slum upgrading, for example in some rapidly urbanizing African cities. The application of this LR approach to countries where the technique has never been used is still at an experimental stage. Potential pilot projects are being designed, but have not been fully implemented, so further research is needed to test the validity of assertions about this approach.
Challenges of Urbanization
In 2010, about 50.7 percent of the world’s population (3.5 billion people) lived in urban areas (World Bank 2011). The percentage is expected to increase to 70 percent by 2050, mostly in the periphery of secondary cities in developing countries. According to UN-HABITAT (2011), one-third of the urban population in developing countries (1.2 billion people) lives in slums and, despite substandard living conditions, these populations are increasing, especially in Sub-Saharan Africa and the Asia-Pacific region. Between 2000 and 2010, the number of slum dwellers increased by six million annually (Cities Alliance 2011).
Unfortunately, infrastructure and basic service development in most African countries have not increased at the same rate. Cities where sanitation, roads, water, and other services were already underdeveloped have limited fiscal resources and struggle with accommodating the unprecedented increase in population. Two major problems that hinder urban upgrading are holdouts in land assembly and lack of public funds to finance infrastructure—issues to which we will return.
Natural disasters also have taken a toll on urban populations. According to a United Nations estimate, earthquakes, tsunamis, landslides, floods, and volcano eruptions caused economic damage totaling $109 billion in 2010, three times more than in 2009 (Reuters 2011). Cities in developing countries with poor infrastructure and fiscal health are particularly vulnerable and are facing increasing price tags for both post-disaster reconstruction and adaptation to future calamities. Again, solving the problems associated with land assembly and infrastructure financing are crucial.
Conventional solutions for dealing with land assembly problems, such as compulsory purchase (eminent domain) and market transactions, are onerous. With increasing global demands for democratic governance and the realization of human rights to adequate housing, secure tenure, and protection from forced eviction, the traditional approach of relying on coercive measures that take land from owners or occupants for urban expansion and redevelopment is encountering strong legal opposition and public protests (table 1).
Using the market to facilitate voluntary land transfers is also problematic. Holdouts by individual landowners could thwart the redevelopment project and increase compensation costs for land acquisition. In some African countries where market mechanisms are not yet fully developed, unequal access to information has led to land grabs and speculation by local elites. As a result, the urban poor were either forced out or bought out from their neighborhoods and were relocated to remote areas where access to employment, public transportation, and basic services are limited.
To make matters worse, the fiscal outlook for cities in developing countries is bleak, and the opportunities to speed up the construction or repair of housing and basic infrastructure are limited. The 2008 subprime mortgage market meltdown in the United States has had adverse repercussions for municipal finances around the world. The decline in demand for imports in industrialized nations and the tightening of liquidity in the financial markets has slowed global economic growth. As exports to developed countries decrease, income-tax and value-added-tax collections in less developed nations also drop. The reduction in tax revenues exacerbates the already tight local budgets and further undermines the ability of municipalities to repair disaster-damaged infrastructure or build new facilities to accommodate rapid population growth.
Land Readjustment as an Alternative
LR has been practiced in many countries to achieve policy goals ranging from farmland consolidation to inner-city revitalization (Doebele 1982; Hong and Needham 2007). Its basic principle is to organize landowners to act collectively—in cooperation with a municipality and/or private developer—to pool their land in order to accomplish a redevelopment project.
LR is often used to re-parcel land when existing parcel boundaries are in conflict with the current land use plan. One important outcome is that a portion of the readjusted land can be retained by the development agency for construction of necessary infrastructure and basic services. If LR is not used, this land would have to be acquired by the local government, which could entail a huge upfront cost.
In return for the owners’ or occupants’ land contribution to the project, each participant receives, upon completion of the program, a new parcel proportionate in size or value to the original one. The size of the parcel may be smaller, but the value is greater due to land improvements and infrastructure created by the project. In this way, LR generates desirable urban development patterns, increases land values, allocates these increments to the involved parties, and limits displacement.
What is important about the recent interest in LR is its renewed emphasis as a mechanism for building legal and social institutions to govern urban development. The major goal is to combine job creation, land use planning, urban densification, public-private partnerships, and value capture for public infrastructure financing in one comprehensive policy package.
Potential Advantages and Disadvantages
Different elements of this unified goal can be emphasized depending on the context. For instance, in the design of a LR project for urban upgrading in an African city where residents do not have legal property rights, policy makers can legitimatize the occupants’ claims to land and allow them to exercise their right to participate in the project. After land is pooled, readjusted, and serviced, the residents will be invited back to the neighborhood to rebuild their homes or receive an apartment unit with legal title. This is a win-win approach because it allows squatters to improve their living conditions and tenure security, and it increases development densities to enable the city to obtain much-needed land for urban expansion.
LR can also help implement citywide land use regulation incrementally. To ensure that individual LR projects add up to a coherent whole, they must be conducted as part of a comprehensive urban planning process. In situations where local governments lack the capacity to execute a large-scale master plan, related LR projects can be implemented in an orderly sequence and at a manageable scale to put into action a coordinated, long-term development strategy.
In addition, LR can engender democratic governance. The core principle of LR is to build consensus and cooperation among the parties involved in land development. These parties include formal landowners, informal landholders, renters, NGOs, national government agencies, city officials, and private developers. The process entails grassroots mobilization by giving the urban poor real bargaining power to approve LR proposals. Agreement from the supermajority of landowners and renters is required before LR can proceed, thus ensuring that the government (or a private organizing agency) will pay special attention to the needs of the underprivileged groups and avoid confrontation caused by the threat of forced eviction at the very beginning of the project.
Finally, LR can facilitate land value capture for financing local infrastructure and social services. In readjusting the land boundaries, land space is created by increasing development densities. This land space can then be sold in the market to raise funds to defray a portion of the infrastructure costs. This technique creates a clear connection between the development benefits received by landholders and the price that they need to pay to make the program financially viable.
Despite these potential advantages of LR over conventional land assembly methods, it is hardly quick or uncomplicated. LR is particularly difficult to implement in developing countries where public participation is not integrated into urban planning or where there is limited capacity to maintain ownership records and resolve competing land claims. When property owners do not recognize their obligation to pay for basic infrastructure and services, requests to give up a portion of their land to cover the project costs will be strongly resisted.
Another concern is that LR reduces plot sizes, causing problems in many informal settlements where people often rely on extra space to earn rental income or conduct agricultural and business activities. In some cases, urban legislation is often too rigid for facilitating LR. Furthermore, different stakeholders may value real assets in diverse ways, making consensus building difficult. Some see possible improvements in living conditions, neighborhood amenities, social networks, and cohesiveness of community as the predominant factors. Others may make their decision based solely on monetary gains.
The integrated LR approach is designed to target all of these issues by focusing on institutional design and development. It emphasizes learning from past LR experiences to illustrate the importance of local context and enhancing this tool to accommodate a wide range of variables and situations. In addition, future adoption of the technique will search for a good fit rather than a single best practice. Most fundamentally, the design of LR projects must be based on multiple perspectives ranging from political economy and anthropological approaches to legal investigation.
Designing Land Readjustment in Chile
On February 27, 2010, a massive earthquake and tsunami destroyed a large part of Central Chile. Three regions—O’Higgins, Maule, and Bio-Bio—comprising 5 major cities and 45 small towns were seriously damaged; more than 80,000 homes were destroyed, and about 108,000 units were severely damaged (figure 1).
In response to this unprecedented disaster, the Chilean government expanded its National Reconstruction Plan to include new mandates and more flexible policies to speed up its post-earthquake reconstruction efforts. This plan offers four types of assistance in the form of vouchers to affected families: (1) US$24,144 for rebuilding a new home on existing land; (2) US$19,083 for buying a new home in another neighborhood; (3) US$3,761 for repairing houses that were partially destroyed; and (4) a special bonus of US$4,200 if the destroyed house is located in a heritage zone (Ministry of Housing and Urban Development 2011).
Despite this financial assistance from the government, affected property owners are facing two major problems. First, because the reconstruction program gives priority to low-income households, the money provided by the state to middle-income families is insufficient for them to rebuild homes of the same size and quality or in the same neighborhood. Property owners without insurance coverage who want to build a similar house must sell their land and move to another neighborhood where the land price is lower. Those who live in tsunami-damaged areas now considered unsafe for redevelopment must resettle further inland, yet that may limit their access to jobs and public services.
Second, selling their land to finance reconstruction may not be a viable option for all affected residents. Some landowners refuse to sell to private developers who offer a low price because the property is so badly damaged. Others who are unable to sell their land may not have sufficient financial resources to rebuild. This persistence of unlivable houses and vacant lots covered with debris further dampens the private incentive to reinvest in the neighborhood.
To assist the post-earthquake reconstruction effort, the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and the ProUrbana Program in the Public Policy Center at the Catholic University of Chile (the team) put forward a joint proposal to the Chilean government to experiment with LR.
The Pilot Project: Las Heras, Talca
The team decided to conduct its first pilot in the Las Heras neighborhood in Talca for four reasons.
First, Las Heras was ripe for redevelopment even before the earthquake. It is a middle-class neighborhood with large old houses and a beautiful main square. Good social networks exist among its residents, organized by the church and local NGOs, although its development had stagnated for many years due to economic restructuring of the Chilean economy. The central government was offering Las Heras assistance in developing affordable housing through the national voucher program, and these housing subsidies later became an important potential funding source for the proposed LR project.
Second, the Public Policy Center has another program called Puentes (Bridges) that conducts collaborative research projects with local municipalities, including a preexisting work agreement with Talca, which facilitated prompt support and cooperation from city officials.
Third, Talca has a master plan that allowed the team to design a series of related LR projects to be implemented step-by-step, so it could fulfill the city’s long-term development plan. Preliminary land ownership and demographic information, land use data, and property damage assessments in different neighborhoods are also available.
Fourth, the local government and private developers in Talca were interested in increasing urban densities. Densification provided the much-needed profit incentive for the private sector to redevelop damaged sites, and it could help the local government achieve its objective of increasing and upgrading the housing supply.
Buy-In from All Involved Parties
Following the integrated LR approach, the team recognized the importance of gaining support from the central government. It organized a seminar in Santiago in May 2010 to present the concept of LR and exchange views with top officials from the Ministry of Housing and Urban Development (MHUD). After several rounds of follow-up discussions, the director of the National Program of Housing Reconstruction agreed to purchase reserved land generated from the proposed LR project, thus providing a guarantee for one of the funding sources, and agreed to go to Talca with the team to encourage property owners to participate.
To obtain critical local government involvement, the team travelled to Talca in September 2010 to present the LR ideas to city officials. The team also met with selected property landowners to determine if they might be interested in contributing all or part of their land as capital to finance the reconstruction of their homes and neighborhood. In another visit, some team members also met with school and community leaders, emphasizing the need for broad community support for the project’s success.
The team next began to gather detailed data about the area by conducting a survey of residents in eight blocks comprising 217 lots near the main plaza of Las Heras (figure 2). Team members completed 135 questionnaires over the telephone and then interviewed selected residents. The survey results indicated that 77 percent of the respondents trusted their neighbors, and the majority of them (65 percent) wanted to stay in the neighborhood and were willing to work with their neighbors to rebuild the community. Only 12 percent of respondents planned to sell their property and relocate to another area. This information revealed that organizing property owners for LR was feasible.
Project Design
Because the majority of residents in Las Heras are unfamiliar with the concept of LR, the strategy started with a small pilot project to demonstrate the applicability of this method. The team chose a block near the plaza and proposed three scenarios for combining 8 to 12 sites for LR. The number of lots included in the proposed project would depend on the levels of difficulty involved in negotiating with affected property owners. To facilitate the participation process, the team prepared visual images of what the neighborhood environment might look like after the project (figure 3).
The team also conducted detailed financial and legal feasibility studies for the project. A tentative plan for financing the pilot included a careful calculation of the amount of land that each owner would need to contribute based on the availability of government subsidies, estimated building costs, compensation for temporary relocation, and a projected land price at the completion date of the project. The financial study also revealed that constructing housing units at an estimated future price of US$46,000 per unit would allow the project to be self-financing and provide the developer with a 10 percent profit margin—under the assumption that MHUD would purchase the reserved land to build affordable housing for low- and low-to-middle-income households after LR. It was also estimated that 24 percent of the housing units within the block would be affordable for low-income households. This would help the MHUD attain its policy goal of social integration through the provision of subsidized housing.
The Real Estate Co-ownership Law in Chile requires all participating owners of the LR project to sign a legal document specifying their rights and liabilities. For example, any sale of land held by the designated organizing agency would require the consensus of all participating owners. A legal contract signed by the agency and each participating owner would specify explicitly the number of housing units that the owner would receive at the end of the project and the date of the delivery. The contract would also guarantee compliance by requiring the agency to pay compensation to owners in case of failure to transfer properties in a timely manner and of acceptable quality. The agency also needs to submit the proposed plan to the city. The Municipal Works Department would review the project, approve the building plan, and authorize the transfer of land. The approved plan would then be recorded by the registrar.
Although the research conducted by the team shows that LR is feasible in Las Heras, progress in convincing landowners to participate has been slow due to five key challenges.
First, most property owners are unfamiliar with LR, and there is no existing example in Chile to show how the idea could work. The lack of precedents makes community organizing difficult.
Second, city officials have not provided sufficient support in organizing community meetings or interacting with property owners directly about the proposed project.
Third, many affected property owners who received assistance from their extended families or friends have already relocated to other areas. These owners are in no hurry to rebuild their homes and are delaying the transfer of their land until they receive a higher offer from a private developer or the government. In Chile, there is no LR law that can force these owners to transfer their real assets.
Fourth, not all buildings in the neighborhood were destroyed by the earthquake, and the owners of the unaffected homes are not willing to give up their existing plots for a neighborhood-wide redevelopment.
Fifth, although the survey shows that many owners are willing to work on rebuilding with their neighbors, solving local problems through collective action is not a social norm in Chile. Some property owners have a strong sense of entitlement to receive public resettlement assistance, which contradicts the idea of community self-help.
Interim Assessment
Although the LR approach in Las Heras is still a work-in-progress and it is too soon to predict if the team will be able to overcome local challenges, the project has already generated several observable impacts on Chile’s post-earthquake reconstruction policy (Public Policy Center 2011).
First, LR gives property owners in Las Heras an additional option for reconstructing their homes. Before the proposal, they had to either sell their properties to a private developer and move to another area or take the government’s subsidies and rebuild a house of smaller size and lower quality. LR provides residents with the opportunity to remain in the neighborhood and to attain the highest possible living standard by using their land as capital for home reconstruction.
Second, LR opens a new channel for the central government to work with local communities on reconstruction projects. The main reasons that the LR proposal for Las Heras could go forward are MHUD’s willingness to buy land, provide assistance in encouraging landowners to participate in LR, and give participating landowners the first priority to receive government housing vouchers to finance reconstruction.
Third, the introduction of LR has influenced the government’s overall post-earthquake reconstruction strategy. Through this holistic approach, public officials are designing a comprehensive reconstruction plan to rebuild the entire neighborhood coherently, rather than giving subsidies to individual homeowners to rebuild their houses separately. The MHUD has also invited the team to assist its reconstruction effort in the earthquake-damaged city of Constitución, indicating that the government has taken LR seriously as a viable option for other projects.
Fourth, all discussions among the central and local governments, landowners, NGOs, developers, scholars, and urban designers about LR have engendered an environment of mutual learning and understanding, which in turn is reshaping the governance structure for post-earthquake reconstruction. The involved parties have begun to realize that neither a top-down nor a bottom-up approach is sufficient to generate satisfactory solutions. Cooperation among all interested parties is paramount. The LR experiment has fostered a social discourse that helps all segments of society learn how to solve their problems collectively.
Conclusion
Like all policy experiments, the current proposals to test the integrated LR approach for urban upgrading and post-disaster reconstruction in countries where the idea is new will face uncertainties and challenges. Yet, given the mixed outcomes of conventional land assembly methods in many (re)development situations, LR could offer another option for policy makers, practitioners, and other interested parties to consider.
About the Authors
Yu-Hung Hong is a senior fellow of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and a visiting assistant professor at Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Isabel Brain, a sociologist, coordinates the ProUrbana Program (Program of Urban and Land Policy) at the Public Policy Center, Catholic University of Chile in Santiago.
References
Cities Alliance. 2011. World statistics day: A look at urbanisation. Washington, DC. http://www.citiesalliance.org/ca/node/2195
Doebele, William A. 1982. Land readjustment: A different approach to financing urbanization. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Hong, Yu-Hung, and Barrie Needham. 2007. Analyzing land readjustment: Economics, law, and collective action. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Ministry of Housing and Urban Development, Government of Chile. 2011. Reconstruction Plan (English version). Santiago, Chile: Ministry of Housing and Urban Development.
Public Policy Center. 2011. Land readjustment project, second report. Santiago: Catholic University of Chile. May.
Reuters. 2011. Cost of natural disasters $109 billion in 2010. January 24. http://www.reuters.com/article/2011/01/24/us-disasters-un-idUSTRE70N26K2…
UN-HABITAT. 2011. State of the world’s cities 2010/2011–Cities for all: Bridging the urban divide. Nairobi, Kenya: United Nations Human Settlements Program.
World Bank. 2011. Data: Urban population. Washington, DC. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.URB.TOTL
Acknowledgments
The authors thank the other members of the LR project team for their contributions to this article: Armando Carbonell, Department of Planning and Urban Form, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy; Pia Mora, ProUrbana, Public Policy Center, Catholic University of Chile; Julio Poblete, DUPLA/Urban Design and Planning; Alejandra Rasse, Catholic University of Maule; Francisco Sabatini, Institute of Urban and Territorial Studies, Catholic University of Chile; and Martim Smolka, Program on Latin America and the Caribbean, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Es para mí un honor suceder a Gregory K. Ingram como quinto presidente del Lincoln Institute of Land Policy (ver página 28) y participar junto con ustedes en mi número inaugural de Land Lines. Será un gran desafío para mí poder estar a la altura de la capacidad de liderazgo de Greg y los años extraordinariamente productivos desde que él se hizo cargo del Instituto en 2005. Espero poder combinar mis habilidades y experiencia con las formidables herramientas y el talentoso personal del Instituto para continuar con nuestra misión singular: conectar a académicos, funcionarios públicos y líderes empresariales para combinar la teoría y la práctica de las políticas de suelo con el fin de abordar una gran variedad de desafíos sociales, económicos y medioambientales.
Hay fuerzas tectónicas —naturales, artificiales o ambas— que están dando nueva forma a nuestro planeta. A medida que confrontamos el cambio climático, la aceleración de la urbanización en Asia y África, el envejecimiento de las poblaciones de Europa y América del Norte, la suburbanización de la pobreza en los Estados Unidos y la insolvencia económica de las ciudades estadounidenses, las decisiones sobre el uso del suelo que tomemos hoy dictarán la calidad de vida de cientos de millones de personas en los próximos cien años. Hay una demanda crítica de planes y políticas integrales que regulen de manera equitativa el uso del suelo, sistemas políticos y sociales que garanticen la sostenibilidad, y análisis económicos sólidos con los que abordar estos desafíos, y esta demanda seguirá siendo alta durante las próximas décadas.
En este número de Land Lines, autores estrechamente relacionados con el Instituto Lincoln exploran estos temas. La fellow Lincoln/Loeb de 2013, Lynn Richards, próxima presidente del Congreso para el Nuevo Urbanismo, expone 10 pasos ingeniosos que las comunidades de los Estados Unidos han tomado para hacer sus suburbios más accesibles a los peatones, con viviendas económicas para compensar la suburbanización de la pobreza y emprendimientos más densos de uso mixto y transporte público para reducir el uso del automóvil y ayudar a retrasar el cambio climático. La arquitecta y fellow Lincoln/Loeb de 2014, Helen Lochhead, analiza los proyectos ganadores de Rebuild by Design (Reconstrucción por Diseño), el concurso internacional que promovió innovaciones de diseño para integrar resiliencia, sostenibilidad y habitabilidad en las regiones afectadas por la supertormenta Sandy. El Director de Relaciones Públicas Anthony Flint informa sobre el séptimo Foro periodístico anual del Instituto Lincoln sobre el suelo y el entorno edificado, que exploró opciones para realizar inversiones más inteligentes y equitativas en infraestructura en las ciudades del siglo XXI. Finalmente, en el Perfil académico, el analista de investigación senior del Instituto Lincoln, Adam Langley, comenta la base de datos de ciudades fiscalmente estandarizadas (FiSC) del Instituto, una nueva herramienta que servirá de base para nuevos análisis importantes que guiarán las respuestas locales a los desafíos fiscales de los Estados Unidos.
Y ahora un poco sobre mí. En los últimos 14 años trabajé en la Fundación Ford, donde ocupé un puesto singular en el sistema filantrópico global que me permitió apoyar, demostrar y ensayar nuevas maneras de resolver importantes problemas sociales. Algunos de los logros que más me enorgullecen son haber creado la Campaña Nacional de Propiedades Vacantes y Abandonadas, para ayudar a construir e incrementar la bolsa de viviendas de patrimonio compartido de la nación, por medio de colaboraciones con la Red Nacional de Fideicomisos de Suelo Comunitario y otras organizaciones asociadas. Ayudé a diseñar y posteriormente lideré Metropolitan Opportunity (Oportunidad Metropolitana), la próxima generación de programación comunitaria y de desarrollo económico de la Fundación, que se propone reducir el aislamiento espacial de las poblaciones necesitadas en regiones metropolitanas integrando la planificación del uso del suelo, el desarrollo de viviendas económicas y la inversión en infraestructura para ofrecer un mejor servicio a todos sus residentes.
Antes de trabajar en la Fundación Ford, había acumulado una gran experiencia en investigación sobre vivienda, economía y análisis de políticas públicas. Tuve la oportunidad de trabajar con académicos de todo el mundo en temas tan diversos como el nacimiento del movimiento medioambiental en Rusia, el papel de los desequilibrios de intercambio comercial y la deuda en los ciclos macroeconómicos y el impacto de la propiedad de la vivienda en las vidas de familias de bajos ingresos. He sido maestro y mentor de miles de estudiantes y he seguido sus logros con gran orgullo. Presenté investigaciones, abogué por cambios políticos y colaboré con éxito con investigadores, activistas y funcionarios públicos en cuatro continentes. Y ahora estoy entusiasmado y me siento honrado por unirme a ustedes en esta aventura con el Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Inclusionary Housing: Creating and Maintaining Equitable Communities
By Rick Jacobus
From Seattle to San Francisco to Chicago to Portland, Maine, debates are raging over inclusionary housing—the requirement that developers reserve a percentage of new residential development as affordable. Some say the policy discourages development—or, in an argument that could reach the Supreme Court, that it threatens property rights. Meanwhile, New York City Mayor Bill de Blasio faces dual criticisms that his inclusionary housing proposal goes too far, or not far enough.
This new report by Rick Jacobus, Inclusionary Housing: Creating and Maintaining Equitable Communities, separates myth from fact, charting a path forward for policy makers and showing how inclusionary housing can be used effectively to reduce economic segregation.
“In hot-market cities, skyrocketing housing prices push middle-class and low-income residents far away from well-paying jobs, reliable transportation, good schools, and safe neighborhoods,” says Lincoln Institute President and CEO George W. McCarthy. “Inclusionary housing alone will not solve our housing crisis, but it is one of the few bulwarks we have against the effects of gentrification—and only if we preserve the units that we work so hard to create.”
Through a review of the literature and case studies, author Rick Jacobus of Street Level Urban Impact Advisors offers solutions for overcoming the major political, technical, legal, and practical barriers to successful inclusionary housing programs.
“More than 500 communities have used inclusionary housing policies to help maintain the vibrancy and diversity of neighborhoods in transition, and we’ve learned much along the way,” Jacobus says. “Research shows that if programs are thoughtfully designed and implemented, they can be a valuable tool at a time when affordable housing is desperately needed.”
In particular, the report addresses the concern that inclusionary housing can impede new construction by making development less profitable. According to the report, many cities have avoided such impacts by allowing flexibility in how developers comply and offering incentives, such as the ability to build at greater densities.
Other key findings and recommendations in the report include:
The Lincoln Institute has for many years developed strategies to support permanently affordable housing, including the establishment of community land trusts and other shared-equity arrangements. The effort is in recognition of the ongoing housing affordability crisis in many cities. Stratospheric rents and home prices in hot real estate markets are displacing longtime residents and changing the character of cities and neighborhoods.
To order, visit http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/3583_Inclusionary-Housing.
Rick Jacobus, a national expert in inclusionary housing and affordable home ownership, is the principal of Street Level Urban Impact Advisors (StreetLevelAdvisors.com). He was the founder of Cornerstone Partnership, and he currently serves as a strategic advisor to Cornerstone.
Una versión más actualizada de este artículo está disponible como parte del capítulo 7 del CD-ROM Perspectivas urbanas: Temas críticos en políticas de suelo de América Latina.
Edesio Fernandes, abogado y urbanista brasileño radicado en Londres, es profesor con dedicación parcial de la Unidad de Planificación para el Desarrollo del University College de Londres. También se desempeña como coordinador de IRGLUS (Grupo internacional de Investigación sobre Legislación y Espacio Urbano) y es asociado de las Naciones Unidas/HABITAT. Entre sus intereses de investigación y docencia figuran la legislación, planificación y política de la gestión urbana y ambiental; la administración municipal y de ciudad y la legislación constitucional y los derechos humanos de países en vías de desarrollo. Durante las dos décadas pasadas ha trabajado activamente en el campo de regularización de suelos urbanos en América Latina y otras regiones.
Fernandes es coordinador de la Red latinoamericana de regularización del suelo urbano del Instituto Lincoln y ha dado clases en el Instituto durante varios años. Trabajó en la organización y enseñanza de un curso sobre regularización y mercados informales del suelo, realizado en octubre de 2001 y nuevamente en noviembre de 2002 en Lincoln House. En esta conversación con Martim Smolka, Senior Fellow y Director del Programa para América Latina y El Caribe del Instituto Lincoln, se exploran algunos de estos temas.
Martim Smolka: ¿Qué despertó su interés en el tema de los mercados informales del suelo y las políticas de regularización?
Edesio Fernandes: Mi interés en los problemas de los mercados informales del suelo se remonta al comienzo de la década de 1980. Poco después de graduarme de la Escuela de Leyes de la Universidad Federal de Minas de Gerais en Belo Horizonte, Brasil, comencé a trabajar para PLAMBEL, la agencia estatal encargada de la planificación metropolitana de Belo Horizonte. Esta ciudad, si bien fue una de las pocas planeadas de Brasil, fue proyectada con mapas y planos que no contemplaban zonas para las personas de bajos recursos que construyeron la ciudad. Para 1895, dos años antes de su inauguración, ya había 3000 personas viviendo en favelas.
Ese número creció considerablemente a lo largo de las décadas de intensa urbanización. En 1976 se aprobó un plan pionero de zonificación, pero nuevamente las favelas fueron pasadas por alto y se trataron como áreas no ocupadas. En 1983 participé en el equipo interdisciplinario Pro-FAVELA, que redactó una fórmula legal para incorporar estas áreas bajo un esquema revisado de zonificación. Fueron precisamente estos primeros trabajos como urbanista, así como mis labores de construcción de puentes académicos entre los estudios jurídicos y urbanos, que me permitieron explorar la naturaleza de la relación entre las leyes, la planificación y la exclusión socioespacial existente en las ciudades del tercer mundo.
MS: En general, ¿ha tenido esa legislación algún efecto en el estado de las favelas de Belo Horizonte y Brasil?
EF: Hasta la década de 1970 la política oficial brasileña hacia las favelas había sido de desalojo o abandono, con la ocasional prestación de servicios limitados exclusivamente por conveniencia política. El programa Pro-FAVELA fue una experiencia sin precedentes que persiguió materializar ese nuevo compromiso democrático a la inclusión sociopolítica y socioespacial de las favelas en el paisaje urbano. La fórmula aprobada se ha convertido en un paradigma de la regularización del suelo urbano en la mayoría de las ciudades brasileñas. La idea es que se deben crear “zonas especiales de interés social” dentro del esquema de zonificación de la ciudad, permitiendo que los reglamentos de planificación y zonificación se adapten a los requisitos específicos de los habitantes de las favelas. Además, la formulación de políticas específicas de tenencia de suelo debe combinarse con mecanismos inclusivos de planificación urbana y también con procesos institucionales participativos de gestión urbana. Esto permite la integración de asentamientos informales en el sistema de planificación formal y la introducción de servicios e infraestructuras para hacer frente a las omnipresentes desigualdades.
MS: ¿Están ya bien integradas estas metas a los sistemas jurídicos y administrativos de las ciudades brasileñas?
EF: Aunque es cierto que la legislación urbana ha mejorado en Brasil, también es cierto que la mayoría de los cursos de leyes no ofrecen módulos especializados en el uso y control del desarrollo del suelo urbano. Desde tiempos inmemoriales los profesionales de leyes—no sólo en Brasil, sino a lo largo de toda América Latina—han aprendido a adoptar un punto de vista obsoleto e individualista sobre los asuntos jurídicos, típico de una legislación liberal clásica no reformada y con una noción de derechos de propiedad absolutos. Como resultado, estas personas desconocen en gran medida los desarrollos jurídicos recientes y las implicaciones legales de la dinámica socioeconómica y los retos que presenta la urbanización acelerada, y no están conscientes del potencial de los diferentes principios jurídicos que apoyan la legislación urbana, sobretodo de la noción de la función social de la propiedad. Por tanto, no están preparados para lidiar con los inevitables conflictos que surgen del uso y desarrollo del suelo urbano.
Sin embargo, en el año 2001 tuvo lugar en Brasil un hito jurídico revolucionario con la aprobación de la Ley Federal n° 10.257 llamada “Estatuto de la Ciudad”, que se propone regular el capítulo original sobre políticas urbanas introducido por la Constitución de 1988. La nueva ley otorga apoyo legal a aquellas municipalidades que se comprometan a confrontar los graves problemas urbanos, sociales y ambientales que afectan directamente al 82 por ciento de los brasileños que habitan en las ciudades. En términos conceptuales, el Estatuto de la Ciudad rompió con la vieja tradición de derecho civil y establece la base para un nuevo paradigma jurídico-político para el uso y el control del desarrollo del suelo urbano. Las municipalidades deben formular políticas territoriales y de uso del suelo que combinen los intereses individuales de los propietarios con los intereses sociales, culturales y ambientales de otros grupos y de la ciudad como un todo. También se les exige integrar la planificación, legislación y gestión urbana con objeto de democratizar el proceso local de toma de decisiones y legitimizar un nuevo orden jurídico urbano con sesgo social. Asimismo, el Estatuto de la Ciudad puso en marcha instrumentos jurídicos para permitir que las municipalidades pongan en marcha programas de regularización de tenencia de suelo y facilitar el acceso a la vivienda y al suelo urbano.
MS: ¿Puede explicar la relación que hay entre la regularización, la seguridad de tenencia de tierra y las crecientes inquietudes sobre pobreza y justicia social?
EF: Por una parte, los programas de regularización que se concentran en proyectos de mejoramiento han tendido a descuidar los asuntos de tenencia de tierra, por ejemplo, el ponderado programa Favela-Bairro de Rio de Janeiro. Esto ha causado que dichos programas suelan tener resultados nocivos, tales como la ocupación por narcotraficantes, expropiación a la fuerza, e incluso—dada la relación cada vez más compleja entre mercados de suelo formales e informales—lo que se conoce como “desalojo por mercado”. Por otra parte, los programas de regularización que se concentran exclusivamente en la titulación formal de parcelas individuales, tales como los programas a gran escala inspirados por las ideas de Hernando de Soto, han tendido a reforzar las condiciones inaceptables de vida y la construcción de viviendas en áreas remotas, con ambientes desfavorables y desprovistas de servicios.
Por experiencia propia, he visto que los programas que han tratado de combinar las dos dimensiones, es decir, mejoramiento y legalización, tienden a ser los más sostenibles en términos urbanos, sociales y ambientales, así como también suelen tener un efecto más controlado en los mercados de suelo tanto formales como informales. Por tanto, pueden tener más eficacia a la hora de garantizar que los beneficiarios finales de la inversión pública sean justamente los habitantes de los asentamientos informales y no los promotores inmobiliarios y empresas constructoras quienes, al no ofrecer opciones que sean costeables, suficientes y adecuadas, son los primeros que han provocado el proceso de desarrollo informal.
MS: ¿Hasta qué punto han podido estos programas de regularización atacar o ayudar a resolver el problema de la pobreza?
EF: Los programas de regularización son siempre medidas curativas que hay que integrar con políticas preventivas de planificación urbana, medidas fiscales y legales y estrategias de gestión diseñadas para promover un cambio urbano general, y consecuentemente poder romper con ese ciclo característico que lleva a la informalidad urbana. Además, la única manera de que tengan un efecto más significativo sobre la pobreza urbana es combinándolos con otros programas que expandan el acceso a servicios urbanos y originen empleos y entradas económicas para aliviar la pobreza.
En esta discusión hay muchas suposiciones que no pueden darse por sentado, especialmente en vista de los resultados de estudios recientes. Durante años se han invertido cuantiosas sumas de dinero en programas de regularización. Ya es hora de hacer una evaluación crítica y completa. Todavía hay muchas interrogantes sin respuesta referentes a la naturaleza de los procesos que desencadenan los asentamientos irregulares, la manera de enfrentar el problema y el método práctico de poner en práctica las políticas, por ejemplo: ¿Cómo se originan los asentamientos informales? ¿Por qué es importante regularizarlos? ¿Cuándo y cómo se deben formular los programas de regularización? ¿Quién debe pagar por ellos, y cómo? ¿Qué pasa una vez que finaliza el programa?
MS: Como abogado, ¿qué ha aprendido sobre la propuesta legal a las políticas de titulación?
EF: En particular, debemos cuestionar críticamente ese razonamiento tan aceptado que proclama que los títulos son la condición fundamental para que los habitantes de los asentamientos informales tengan acceso a servicios y a crédito y, por ende, para invertir en sus casas y negocios. En general podemos decir que en situaciones consolidadas en donde la ocupación informal del suelo ha sido respaldada por la movilización sociopolítica de los residentes, se ha producido el acceso a servicios e infraestructura sin importar el estado legal de dichos residentes. Trabajos de investigación realizados en varios países ya indican que una serie de circunstancias socioeconómicas y político-institucionales puede crear una percepción de “seguridad de tenencia”, lo cual anima a las personas a invertir en mejoras a sus viviendas aun cuando no haya finalizado el proceso de legalización. Las investigaciones también han demostrado que las personas sin dinero y sin empleo no tienen acceso a créditos formales aunque tengan títulos, mientras que en algunos casos, la gente que tiene trabajo pero no títulos sí tiene acceso a crédito.
MS: ¿Sugiere Ud. entonces que la formalización de los títulos legales no es tan importante?
EF: No, lo que quiero decir es que aunque los títulos pueden aportar seguridad de tenencia individual, no garantizan necesariamente el acceso al crédito formal ni producen asentamientos sostenibles. La regularización por sí sola suele fracasar en lo que, en mi opinión, debería ser el objetivo máximo de los programas de regularización, es decir, la integración socioespacial de las comunidades y áreas informales. Ahora bien, los títulos son claramente importantes desde muchos puntos de vista, por ejemplo, para resolver conflictos domésticos, de familia y de vecindad y para reconocer legalmente los derechos sociopolíticos. El desafío planteado aquí es promover el reconocimiento de la seguridad de tenencia individual de una manera que sea compatible con la provisión de vivienda social, y de esa manera eliminar—o al menos reducir al mínimo posibleÔel proceso de segregación socioespacial. La única manera de lograr esto es mediante una combinación de mecanismos de planificación urbana y estrategias de gestión de ciudad, con políticas innovadoras de tenencia de suelo, con énfasis en la existencia de una gran variedad de opciones legales aparte de los derechos que implican la propiedad absoluta.
MS: El Instituto Lincoln ha participado activamente en estas materias en Latinoamérica durante casi diez años. ¿Tiene Ud. algún comentario final sobre cómo podemos ampliar esta labor?
EF: La centralidad de esta discusión de materias de suelo interrelacionadas—estructura de suelo, acceso al suelo y vivienda, gestión del suelo y control de desarrollo y planificación de uso del suelo—goza de un reconocimiento internacional cada vez mayor, lo cual confirma la importancia de los objetivos originales del Instituto Lincoln y de su programa general de investigación y enseñanza. El tema de desarrollo de suelo urbano informal es de interés para cualquiera que tenga inquietudes relacionadas con la justicia social y los derechos humanos, así como con las condiciones para la expansión de mercados en el contexto de globalización económica.
Para finalizar, quisiera realzar la importancia de la educación y discurso legales. Los cambios urbanos exigen reformas legales, las cuales a su vez requieren un entendimiento adecuado de la naturaleza, problemas y desventajas del orden jurídico imperante y de las posibilidades de cambio consiguientes. Es crucial seguir promocionando actividades comparativas de investigación y enseñanza como las que ya lleva a cabo el Instituto, así como también apoyar redes académicas y políticas tales como IRGLUS y la Red latinoamericana de regularización del suelo urbano. Hay un grupo muy pequeño de profesionales que ha explorado las interfases latinoamericanas entre legislación y planificación y entre legalidad e ilegalidad desde un punto de vista sociojurídico crítico; ese grupo necesita crecer. Hoy más que nunca es fundamental construir caminos jurídicos que respalden nuevos intentos de promover cambios urbanos positivos, incluidos los programas de regularización. Esto no es tarea fácil, pero estamos haciendo progreso.
Una versión más actualizada de este artículo está disponible como parte del capítulo 5 del libro Perspectivas urbanas: Temas críticos en políticas de suelo de América Latina.
Pocos países de América Latina (o del resto del mundo) se han atrevido a poner en práctica reformas tan radicales de la política de tierras urbanas como lo ha hecho Chile en los últimos 20 años. En 1979 el gobierno comenzó a aplicar las políticas de desregulación mediante la publicación de un documento donde se establecía que la escasez de la tierra era un producto artificial de la excesiva regulación, que había llevado a la virtual eliminación de los límites de crecimiento urbano.
Desde entonces ha habido cambios numerosos en la morfología y estructura interna de las ciudades chilenas, pero la evaluación de dichos cambios varía según la posición ideológica de quien evalúa. Si bien las políticas urbanas explícitas de orientación social han propiciado un mejoramiento significativo en lo que se refiere al acceso a la vivienda para la población de bajos recursos, algunas personas sostienen que la segregación espacial derivada de tales políticas ha perjudicado a la sociedad al indirectamente disminuir la calidad de vida, impedir el acceso al trabajo y agravar la alienación social.
Incluso antes del período del gobierno militar de 1973 a 1990, Chile estaba reconocido por su sistema político unitario y centralista, caracterizado por una fuerte presencia del Estado en la economía y la política. Esta sociedad con cultura relativamente homogénea se diferencia de otros países latinoamericanos por su fuerte tradición legalista. De la misma manera, las ciudades chilenas exhiben marcados contrastes cuando se las compara con sus homólogas latinoamericanas. Prácticamente no hay mercados de tierra informales; la tenencia de la tierra ha sido casi completamente regularizada mediante programas públicos radicales; y la mayoría de los pobres urbanos viven en áreas urbanizadas cuyas calles principales están pavimentadas. La violencia urbana, a pesar de su tendencia creciente, es aún mínima si se la compara con el resto del continente.
Políticas y problemas de la liberalización
Entre los aspectos más innovadores de la política urbana chilena figuran los siguientes:
Si bien, algunos de los logros de estas políticas de liberalización se han reconocido ampliamente como positivos -particularmente en lo que se refiere a la regularización legal y física o urbanística y la cantidad de vivienda social proporcionada- muchos chilenos creen que las políticas de los últimos 20 años han sido una fuente de nuevos problemas, entre ellos:
No está claro si estos cambios urbanos pueden atribuirse directamente a la eficacia de las políticas urbanas de mercado, o a la positiva evolución de la economía chilena en general. El crecimiento sostenido del producto interno bruto (GDP), con un promedio del 7 % anual desde 1985, se interrumpió sólo recientemente debido a los efectos de la crisis asiática.
Expansión del debate
A pesar de que la liberalización de los mercados de suelo urbano en Chile constituye una experiencia interesante e innovadora desde un punto de vista internacional, el debate público interno ha sido limitado. No obstante, los logros y problemas de la liberalización han llegado a tal punto de importancia que últimamente han estimulado un nivel generalizado de preocupación y una variedad de planteamientos al respecto. Más aún, el gobierno está proponiendo una serie de modificaciones de la actual “Ley General de Urbanismo y Construcciones”, que traerían consigo un número de cambios significativos, entre ellos:
Con el fin de facilitar una discusión concentrada en los temas anteriores, Carlos Montes, Presidente de la Cámara de Diputados de Chile, invitó al Instituto Lincoln a participar en un seminario coordinado con el Instituto de Estudios Urbanos de la Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile. El seminario, llamado “A 20 años de la liberalización de los mercados de suelo urbano en Chile: Impactos en la política de vivienda social, el crecimiento urbano y los precios del suelo”, tuvo lugar en octubre de 1999 en la ciudad de Santiago. Allí se reunieron miembros del Congreso chileno y de la comunidad comercial (promotores, líderes financieros, etc.), oficiales de organismos públicos (ministerios, municipalidades, etc.), académicos y representantes de organizaciones no gubernamentales para participar en un animado debate. En la discusión se notó una marcada polarización ideológica entre las metodologías “liberal” y “progresiva” utilizadas para entender y resolver los asuntos de la liberalización, es decir, “más mercado” frente a “más Estado”.
Desde el punto de vista liberal4, estos problemas emergen y persisten debido a que los mercados de tierra no han sido nunca suficientemente liberalizados. De hecho, algunos liberales insisten en que la intervención pública no desapareció nunca, y creen que la regulación más bien aumentó después de que Chile retornara a la democracia en 1990. Por ejemplo, los liberales citan varios medios, a menudo indirectos, que utiliza el Estado para restringir el libre crecimiento de las ciudades, tales como cuando se intenta ampliar áreas designadas con protección ambiental y cerradas a usos urbanos, o se impone un criterio oficial y casi homogéneo de densificación para todo espacio urbano. También aseveran que los ciudadanos deberían tener la libertad de elegir diferentes estilos de vida, y que las autoridades deberían limitarse a informar a los ciudadanos sobre el costo privado y social de sus opciones, con el entendimiento implícito de que tales costos están reflejados en los precios del mercado cuando hay un funcionamiento eficaz de los mercados de suelo urbano, es decir, cuando están completamente liberalizados.
La principal explicación ofrecida por los liberales sobre los problemas de equidad y eficiencia que enfrenta el desarrollo urbano chileno actual son los avances insuficientes en la aplicación de criterios para “internalizar las externalidades”, particularmente externalidades negativas, por aquellos que son responsables por ellas. Tal como lo han clamado apasionadamente algunos de los representantes de este grupo, se debería permitir a los agentes privados actuar con libertad, siempre que éstos estén dispuestos a hacerse cargo de los costos sociales involucrados.
Por otra parte, los progresistas creen que la liberalización se ha excedido en su abordaje de mercado y ha dejado muchos problemas sin resolver, tales como el aumento en los precios del suelo; los problemas en la calidad y durabilidad de la vivienda; las condiciones de servicio de la tierra; los problemas sociales asociados con la pobreza urbana; y los problemas de eficiencia y equidad derivados de los patrones de crecimiento de las ciudades, p. ej., la disparidad entre áreas dotadas de servicios públicos y las localidades seleccionadas para proyectos privados de desarrollo.
Estas críticas reconocen la naturaleza imperfecta de los mercados urbanos y la necesidad de tener mayores niveles de control e intervención. Entre las formas de intervención recomendadas por muchos progresistas se encuentran los instrumentos de captura de plusvalía, los cuales raramente han sido empleados o incluso contemplados en programas de financiamiento para la provisión pública de nueva infraestructura y nuevos servicios urbanos. La creación de tales mecanismos apoyaría la idea de internalizar las externalidades, un punto de relativo consenso entre progresistas y liberales. La diferencia principal es que los liberales restringirían la captura de plusvalía a la recuperación pública de costos específicos, mientras que los progresistas considerarían el derecho a capturar la plusvalía entera que resulte de cualquier acción pública, bien sea como resultado de inversión como de regulación.
En términos más generales, los progresistas claman que no todo puede medirse estrictamente en términos monetarios. Hay valores y objetivos urbanos relacionados con la política pública que no pueden conseguirse a través del mercado, ni siquiera por ley, tal como el sentido de comunidad. Aunque mayormente se le desatiende en las nuevas opciones habitacionales facilitadas por promotores privados a familias de bajos recursos, tales como el sistema de vouchers, la solidaridad comunitaria es un asunto de enorme importancia para contrarrestar los problemas sociales que la segregación espacial tiende a exacerbar. La protección ambiental es otro ejemplo de un objetivo de política urbana para el cual las “etiquetas de precios” son de dudosa eficacia.
Con respecto al crecimiento libre de las ciudades y la idea de respetar las opciones para sus ciudadanos, los progresistas apuntan los fuertes costos ambientales y sociales que normalmente acompañan el crecimiento descontrolado. También hacen notar el hecho de que el único grupo que realmente puede elegir su estilo de vida a través del mercado es la minoría pudiente. Si bien conceden que hay beneficios en la concentración, los progresistas también expresan sus inquietudes sobre el exceso de densificación. Algunos chilenos han expresado interés en una autoridad metropolitana que maneje los asuntos regionales, y también en el uso de inversión en infraestructura pública como forma de orientar el crecimiento.
Las respuestas adecuadas a estos asuntos y perspectivas implican algo que va más allá de soluciones técnicas o fiscales, tales como el punto al cual los promotores realmente pagan por el costo total de los cambios que imponen en la sociedad (para no hablar del problema de evaluar los costos con precisión) o la sustentación del sistema de vouchers bajo demanda, que constituye la base de la política habitacional de Chile. Las soluciones también involucran inquietudes de mayor amplitud y con más contenido valórico, tales como los costos ambientales del crecimiento descontrolado y la importancia de mantener las identidades e iniciativas comunitarias locales. La discusión continúa en el Congreso y en otros entornos, pero es de esperar que pase un tiempo antes de que los bandos opuestos lleguen al consenso.
Martim O. Smolka es Senior Fellow y Director del Programa para América Latina del Instituto Lincoln. Francisco Sabatini es profesor asistente de la Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile. Otros contribuyentes a este artículo fueron Laura Mullahy, asistente de investigación, y Armando Carbonell, Senior Fellow, ambos del Instituto Lincoln.
Notas: En contraste con el resto del continente, las drogas no eran un problema mayor en Chile hasta hace poco tiempo.
2 El área metropolitana de Santiago se compone de 35 jurisdicciones administrativo-políticas independientes llamadas comunas.
3 Véase Gareth A. Jones, “Comparative Policy Perspectives on Urban Land Market Reform”, Land Lines, noviembre de 1998.
4 El uso del término “liberal” en este contexto corresponde a su connotación en Chile, la cual se refiere a la fuerte influencia del principio económico del libre mercado, tal como la aboga la teoría desarrollada por la Escuela de Chicago.
Fuentes: Francisco Sabatini y colaboradores, “Segregación social en Santiago, Chile: Conceptos, métodos y efectos urbanos” (monografía, 1999); y Secretaría Ejecutiva de la Comisión de Planificación de Inversiones en Infraestructura de Transporte (SECTRA), “Encuesta de recorridos de origen y destino en Santiago”(1991).
Brasilia, the capital of Brazil, was inaugurated in the early 1960s as a “new city” that was to usher in a new era for Latin American metropolises, demonstrating how the government’s efficient use of land would allow for orderly urban growth. Two basic instruments were provided for this purpose: normative control of the use of land based on a master plan devised by Lucio Costa; and government ownership of land in the federal capital, which would permit the capital to be planned without the kinds of restrictions and conflicts that normally result from private land ownership. However, three and a half decades later, the problems associated with urban development in Brasilia do not differ substantially from those experienced by other large cities in Latin America.
Land Tenure Shortsightedness and Administrative Patronage
Brasilia presents a unique example of urban land management in Latin America because the administration of public land has always been the responsibility of the local government. Nevertheless, the city’s periphery has experienced an explosive rate of growth with its concomitant pattern of irregular land occupation, illegal subdivisions and lack of infrastructure. In Brasilia the possibility of steering the process of urban growth by means of an explicit policy of access to public land has been slowly and irreparably jeopardized by spontaneous (and illegal) land occupation. This shortsighted use of public land is generally dysfunctional for both urban density and public finance, thus hindering the local administration’s efforts to provide infrastructure to these irregular sites.
Furthermore, political influences on the development process have significantly compromised the chances of efficiently managing the supply of public land in Brasilia. In the early 1990s the government distributed about 65,000 lots in areas without any basic infrastructure. Besides reducing the stock of public land, this “land tenure patronage” created the need for new funding sources to finance new infrastructure. Since the main resource available to the Federal District’s Development Agency (Terracap) is the land itself, this patronage policy resulted in the sale of additional public lands to finance infrastructure in irregular settlements. This vicious cycle has caused serious distortions that the present local administration aims to solve by using public land as “capital” to create an effective policy to manage land tenure revenues and urban costs.
The Brasilia experience seems to confirm the arguments of Henry George and others that public land ownership does not per se lead to more balanced and socially egalitarian urban growth. The current local government strategy to define ways to manage revenue from public lands in order to manage the use of urban land indicates a new form of government interaction with the land market. In this sense, the government changes its role from being the principal landowner to becoming the administrator of land benefits.
Public Land as Land Tenure Capital
The core principle of Brasilia’s new strategy of administering land equity is the definition of public land as “land tenure capital.” The use of this land is submitted to a set of strategic actions that transform public land capital into a factor that induces the consolidation of the Federal District’s technological complex. This is the public counterpart in the process of reconverting land use in the city center into an instrument of social promotion in the land tenure regulation program: public lands are used as land assets through sales, leases and partnerships in urban projects.
The use of differentiated land tenure strategies lends more flexibility to the government in coordinating its actions. The search for a balance between initiatives of a social nature and others where the government seeks to maximize its income is now taking on the appearance of an actual policy of public land administration that breaks with former patronage practices.
In this context of exploring new approaches to the use of public land to control urban development in Brasilia, the Lincoln Institute, the Planning Institute of the Federal District and Terracap organized an International Seminar on Management of Land Tenure Revenue and Urban Costs in June 1998.
The program brought together international experts, government secretaries and local administrators with a view to evaluating international experiences in using public lands to finance urban growth in Europe, the United States and Latin America. Martim Smolka of the Lincoln Institute described the relationships between land market operations, land use regulations and the public capture of land value increments. Alfredo Garay, an architect and former planning director for the city of Buenos Aires, reported on experiences in the development of public land around the city’s harbor.
Bernard Frieden of Massachusetts Institute of Technology described how commercial activities on public trust lands in the western United States are used to raise funds for education and other local purposes. Henk Verbrugge, director of Rotterdam’s fiscal agency and The Netherlands’ representative to the International Association of Assessing Officers, described the country’s system of hereditary tenure, a legal regulation by which land can be used for full private use and benefit while remaining under municipal control and economic ownership.
The participants discussed how these experiences compared with the situation in Brasilia and concluded that the success of various strategies for the use of public land depends on the suitability of specific projects to the respective country’s business culture and the institutional practices in effect in the local administration.
Pedro Abramo is a professor at the Institute of Urban and Regional Research and Planning at the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro, Brazil.