Topic: Recuperação de Mais-Valias

Workshop on Emerging Innovations in Conservation Finance

Setembro 27, 2016 - Setembro 29, 2016

Santiago, Chile

Offered in inglês

Watch the Recording


It is a particularly important and auspicious time for the land conservation community in Chile, and across the Americas, to consider the distance traveled over the past several decades and the tremendous challenges they will face over the balance of the twenty-first century. The significance of the moment in Chile is underscored by two ongoing initiatives:

  1. The passage by the Chilean Congress of the Derecho Real de Conservación, which now allows private landowners to protect their land in perpetuity, and
  2. A project now being negotiated by the Government of Chile and Tompkins Conservation that may protect as many as 10 million acres as new or expanded National Parks.

Even in the context of these historic intitiatives, the challenges facing the land conservation communities in Chile and around the globe are very large and complex. Massive amounts of human and financial capital will be required over the remainder of the twenty-first century to fund land conservation initiatives for a range of purposes, including green and gray infrastructure necessary to address:

  • Very rapidly growing demand for renewable energy resources, requiring increased levels of diligence to assure that developers will properly mitigate environmental impacts
  • Accelerating sea-level rise and increasingly intense storm activity, and
  • Changing quantity and quality of fresh water available to human and natural ecosystems leading to increased demand for desalination and water treatment facilities.

Governments alone will be unlikely to supply the trillions of dollars of capital needed to adequately address these and myriad associated challenges to natural systems. It will take some of the world’s best talent, most inventive technologies, and not least, financial ingenuity, coming from the public, private, NGO and academic sectors, to help pass along to future generations the green and biodiverse biosphere now facing ongoing existential threats.

The aim of this workshop is to build on and sharpen concepts that are making, or have the potential to make, a substantial impact on conservation finance in the Western Hemisphere and beyond. These objectives, in turn, serve the larger mission of the International Land Conservation Network (ILCN), which is to connect organizations and people around the world that are accelerating private and civic sector action to protect and steward land and water resources. 

Partners of this workshop include: Las Majadas de Pirque, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies (DRCLAS), Harvard University, Fundacion Robles de Cantillana, Templado, and Que Pasa.


Details

Date
Setembro 27, 2016 - Setembro 29, 2016
Location
Las Majadas de Pirque
Santiago, Chile
Language
inglês

Keywords

Mitigação Climática, Preservação, Gestão Ambiental, Planejamento de Uso do Solo, Saúde Fiscal Municipal, Finanças Públicas, Resiliência, Recuperação de Mais-Valias, Água

Myths and Realities of Public Land Leasing

Canberra and Hong Kong
By Yu-Hung Hong, Março 1, 1999

Many scholars and analysts have suggested that public leasehold systems could allow governments to benefit from a share of future increased land value. Some have even argued that other policy objectives, including stabilizing land prices, controlling land uses and facilitating land redevelopment, could also be achieved through public land leasing. Although these proposals are persuasive at the theoretical level, there is only limited evidence to prove that governments could achieve these policy goals in practice. My research on Canberra and Hong Kong, which have two of the world’s most well developed leasehold systems, examines some of the benefits and problems of public land leasing.

Land Value Capture

Legal scholars have treated property in land as a bundle of rights. According to this perspective, the government can retain the right to own land and assign to a private party the right to use, develop, transfer, inherit and benefit from land. The private party can enjoy the land rights only for a specified time and as stipulated in the land contract. Theoretically, because the government is the landowner, it could retain a portion of the land value increments by asking a lessee to pay:

  • a lump sum of money-called an initial land premium-at the beginning of the lease,
  • an annual land rent,
  • a premium when the lessee modifies lease conditions to acquire additional rights for land redevelopment, and
  • a premium for renewing the land rights when the lease expires.

The Hong Kong leasehold system seems capable of helping the government recoup a large portion of development windfalls from landholders. For the period 1970-1991, I found that the government recaptured, on average, 39 percent of the increased land value from selected land sites through land leasing. This captured value financed an average of 55 percent of the annual infrastructure investment during the same period. (1)

More important, the money collected from leasing is not a substitute for property taxes in Hong Kong. Owners of residential properties must pay annual rates to the government that are 5 percent of the estimated rental value of their flats. Owners of commercial real estate pay a 15 percent property tax on income earned from their rental premises. Combining all land-related revenues, the Hong Kong government could recover, on average, 79 percent of the annual costs of public infrastructure investment.

In Canberra, by contrast, the percentage of infrastructure investment funded by lease revenues was only 5 percent. (See Figure 1.) There are at least two reasons for the difference: the abolition of land rent for residential leases and competition from other cities that weakens government’s ability to collect higher rents on public land.

In the first instance, then-Prime Minister John Gorton abolished all land rent for residential leases in 1970, an action that his opponents charged was designed to rally public support for his reelection. It was estimated that the government transferred 100 million Australian dollars in equity to lessees at that time, resulting in the loss of an important source of revenue. This incident raised the broader issue of politics in public land management, although leasehold systems do not necessarily induce “rent-seeking” behaviors for private or political gain.

Hong Kong’s government seems able to minimize this problem by establishing a tight internal control over the operations of leasing land. It also provides public officials with generous remuneration and fringe benefits to reduce the temptation of corruption. This demonstrates that, in designing a public leasehold system, a government must consider the need for a system of checks and balances to prevent opportunism or political maneuvering. No single person or department within a government should have the unchecked power to decide on the method and timing of allocating land resources.

The second reason for Canberra’s low lease revenues is its keen competition from other Australian cities in attracting capital. If the city government charged high land premiums and rents, businesses and industry would go to other cities. Thus, competition weakens the government’s bargaining position in negotiating with developers on the amount of land premiums or rent for leasing public land. Although Hong Kong also faces competition from other Asian cities, such as Shanghai, Singapore and Taipei, differences in taxation, government structure, business ethics and culture make capital flight less likely in Hong Kong.

This issue of competition is particularly important for developing economies where local governments are eager to attract investment. They may be willing to compromise by collecting a smaller amount of land premiums and rent from both domestic and foreign land investors. The use of land as a source of public funds may require some level of inter- or intra-regional cooperation to prevent developers from playing one government against another.

Land Speculation

In Hong Kong the government’s reliance on land revenues as a source of public funds presents another problem: its financial interest in land conflicts with its public role in stabilizing land prices. The government has relied heavily on initial land premiums because demanding premiums from lessees during lease renewals has proven to be politically difficult. In addition, the assembly of land rights for land redevelopment involves high negotiation costs because most land leases in Hong Kong have multiple leaseholders. These high costs deter private developers from undertaking land redevelopment by acquiring lease rights and modifying contract conditions. As a result, the government is unable to utilize this method fully to recoup land value. As for the land rent, before 1997 the amount of annual rent paid by lessees was fixed and bore no relationship with increases in land value. Hence, the amount of land rent collected has been minimal. (2) (See Figure 2.)

These difficulties have encouraged the government to retain land value at the beginning of the lease. Yet, this method can work only if officials lease land slowly to private developers. A rapid disposition of land when its value is low would impede the government’s ability to recoup land value in the future. Restrictions on land supply, however, have encouraged private land banking and property speculation, leading to high land and property prices and making Hong Kong one of the world’s most expensive cities. (3)

Officials of other countries could avoid this problem by relying more on lease renewals, contract modifications and the annual land rent than on the initial assignment of leases to capture land value. The plausibility of doing so, however, remains an empirical question. The experiences of Hong Kong suggest that such an attempt could encounter strong public resistance and high negotiation costs.

Managing Land Uses

In principle, public leasehold systems allow the government to manage urban growth by incorporating land use regulations into land leases. If lessees do not develop their land according to the lease provisions, the government has the right to take back the land, a contractual right not available to the government when land is privately owned.

To take full advantage of this special land right, the government must be capable of enforcing the contractual agreements. Despite having the ability to repossess land, there is no evidence to show that enforcement costs under public leasehold systems are lower than those found under freehold systems. This is partly because drafting a complete land contract is impossible. Neither public officials nor the contracting party has perfect information, so they cannot account for all contingencies when they negotiate. Contract language is imperfect and subject to interpretation, creating enforcement problems.

In 1995, a special committee was established in Canberra to review its leasehold system.(4) Analysts found that enforcing the lease purpose clause was a major problem in a town called Fyswick because the lease conditions were too complex and ambiguous. Local officials could not evict lessees who breached their contracts. Rather, they gave lessees an amnesty period to regularize their land uses by applying for lease modifications. In the end, lessees paid their modification premiums, but analysts who conducted the study argued that their payments were far less than the fair market value of the land rights obtained by lessees.

In Hong Kong, using lease conditions to control land uses has created a different problem. Although land contracting could give the government the flexibility to control land development in detail on a case-by-case basis, it is extremely inflexible in adjusting to changes in the overall zoning plan over time. As mentioned earlier, the government incorporates land use regulations into land contracts as conditions at the beginning of the lease. Unless lessees initiate a lease modification, these conditions will remain until the lease expires, which could be as long as 50 years in Hong Kong (and 99 years in Canberra).

When the government needs to update the master plan or revise land regulations to accommodate new urban development, the revised rules may be inconsistent with lease conditions established years ago. This problem has created confusion about which planning standards developers in Hong Kong should follow. To make matters worse, any regulatory changes that infringe on the lessees’ contracted land rights may trigger lawsuits against the government. The legal liability has impeded the government’s ability to modernize its land use plan for districts where outdated lease purpose clauses are still in effect.

Urban Redevelopment

Under public leasehold systems, the government can deny a lessee’s application for lease renewal if it needs the land to rebuild the neighborhood or for other public purposes. It can then take back the land and compensate the lessee only for the building. Thus, in theory, leasing should reduce the public costs of land acquisition for urban renewal or other public uses.

The government, however, must wait for leases to expire before it can assemble land for urban renewal. The long duration of land leases could again create a problem. Nor is there evidence that compensation negotiations for buildings are simpler than for both land and buildings. In Hong Kong, issues of holding out and disputes over compensation are as common as in countries where land is privately owned.

Conclusion

The difficulties that Canberra and Hong Kong face in leasing public land show that leasehold systems in and of themselves do not resolve land management problems. This does not mean, however, that leasing is not a viable means to manage land. In Hong Kong, the government retains a large portion of increased land value for public infrastructure investment. Canberra’s public leasehold system enables the government to obtain low-cost land for building the Australian capital.

The important lesson is that policymakers should not set unrealistic expectations on what public leasehold systems can achieve. Failure to deliver their promises could frustrate a well-intended reform and bring the effort to a halt. Because no land tenure system is perfect, the debate should not focus on the choice between leasehold and freehold systems. They are not mutually exclusive. Instead, future research should concentrate on designing specific institutions according to different political, economic and social contexts to minimize problems associated with both systems.

 

Yu-Hung Hong is a visiting fellow of the Lincoln Institute this year. He previously taught at Hong Kong University of Science and Technology in the Division of Social Science, after earning his Ph.D. in urban planning from Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

 


 

Notes

1. See Yu-Hung Hong. 1996. “Can Leasing Public Land be an Alternative Source of Local Public Finance?” Working Paper, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

2. See Yu-Hung Hong. 1998. “Transaction Costs of Allocating Increased Land Value: Hong Kong.” Urban Studies 35, 9: 1577-1595.

3. See Yu-Hung Hong and Alven H.S. Lam. 1998. “Opportunities and Risks of Capturing Land Values under Hong Kong’s Leasehold System.” Working Paper, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

4. Members of the committee included Justice Paul Stein, Patrick Troy and Robert Yeomans. Findings of the review can be found in the Report into the Administration of the ACT Leasehold, published by the government of the Australian Capital Territory in 1995.

Course

Curso de Desarrollo Profesional sobre Gestión de la Valorización Inmobiliaria e Instrumentos No Tributarios de Financiamiento Urbano

Janeiro 29, 2017 - Fevereiro 3, 2017

São Paulo, Brazil

Free, offered in espanhol


Durante este curso se discutirán los asuntos teóricos y métodos prácticos que permiten gestionar la valorización inmobiliaria y utilizarla para superar problemas y desafíos presentes en el desarrollo urbano en América Latina. El curso argumenta que la gestión de las plusvalías o valorización inmobiliaria es central para lograr procesos de ordenamiento y desarrollo urbano socialmente más equitativos, incluyentes y sostenibles.  Se abre una oportunidad única para valorar de forma crítica las posibilidades y límites de  implementación de los instrumentos de recuperación de plusvalías en su país o jurisdicción, con énfasis en instrumentos no tributarios. También permitirá el desarrollo de estrategias para superar los obstáculos legales y políticos responsables de la continuidad de sistemas inequitativos de distribución de cargas y beneficios del proceso de urbanización. Finalmente, se orienta a fortalecer la visión estratégica necesaria para la utilización de instrumentos de recuperación de plusvalías en función de problemas y desafíos concretos. Ver convocatoria.


Details

Date
Janeiro 29, 2017 - Fevereiro 3, 2017
Application Period
Setembro 19, 2016 - Outubro 17, 2016
Selection Notification Date
Novembro 7, 2016 at 6:00 PM
Location
São Paulo, Brazil
Language
espanhol
Cost
Free
Registration Fee
Free
Educational Credit Type
Lincoln Institute certificate

Keywords

Regulação dos Mercados Fundiários, Planejamento, Recuperação de Mais-Valias

Course

Professional Development Course on Large-Scale Urban (Re-)Development Projects

Maio 22, 2016 - Maio 27, 2016

Mexico City, Mexico

Free, offered in espanhol


This professional development course examines large-scale projects designed to promote the redevelopment or regeneration of deteriorated or abandoned urban areas; the extension of the urban perimeter; the strengthening of growth centers; and/or the creation or rehabilitation of central city areas, including historic centers. The course focuses on policies and a broad set of land-based tools and management instruments to finance and fairly redistribute costs and benefits, and/or promote social urban integration. The course presents methodologies to evaluate the impact of these large-scale projects and critically analyzes a wide variety of case studies.


Details

Date
Maio 22, 2016 - Maio 27, 2016
Application Period
Janeiro 15, 2016 - Fevereiro 15, 2016
Selection Notification Date
Fevereiro 29, 2016 at 6:00 PM
Location
Mexico City, Mexico
Language
espanhol
Cost
Free
Registration Fee
Free
Educational Credit Type
Lincoln Institute certificate

Keywords

Desenvolvimento, Desenvolvimento Econômico, Governo Local, Tributação Imobiliária, Finanças Públicas, Urbano

Course

Video Classes on Urban Land Policy

Offered in espanhol


The video classes are multimedia treatments of diverse topics related to urban land policy. Developed to support both moderated and self-paced courses of the Program on Latin America and the Caribbean’s distance education, they are also well suited to generate discussion in neighborhood associations, professional associations, public entities and other groups interested in these topics. Videos are presented primarily in Spanish.


Details

Language
espanhol

Keywords

Estimativa, Cadastro, Computadorizado, Desenvolvimento, Desenvolvimento Econômico, Economia, Meio Ambiente, Planejamento Ambiental, SIG, Habitação, Mercados Fundiários Informais, Infraestrutura, Lei de Uso do Solo, Monitoramento do Mercado Fundiário, Regulação dos Mercados Fundiários, Uso do Solo, Planejamento de Uso do Solo, Valor da Terra, Tributação Imobiliária, Tributação Base Solo, Temas Legais, Governo Local, Mapeamento, Planejamento, Tributação Imobiliária, Finanças Públicas, Políticas Públicas, Favela, Ordem Espacial, Desenvolvimento Sustentável, Tributação, Desenvolvimento Urbano, Melhoria Urbana e Regularização, Urbanismo, Valoração, Recuperação de Mais-Valias, Tributação de Valores

Course

Municipal Fiscal Health and Urban Planning

Julho 4, 2016 - Julho 8, 2016

Beijing, China

Offered in inglês


Each year, the Program on the People’s Republic of China offers a week-long capacity-building “Training the Trainers” course to young faculty members, researchers, and practitioners from universities, government agencies, and institutions across China. The subject of the course varies each year, often targeting to the specific need for knowledge relevant to the current policy reform. The course is taught by internationally-reputed scholars in relevant fields. This year the course topics are Municipal Fiscal Health and Urban Planning.


Details

Date
Julho 4, 2016 - Julho 8, 2016
Location
Peking University
Beijing, China
Language
inglês
Educational Credit Type
Lincoln Institute certificate

Keywords

Infraestrutura, Saúde Fiscal Municipal, Planejamento, Finanças Públicas, Urbano, Desenho Urbano, Desenvolvimento Urbano, Recuperação de Mais-Valias