Thomas J. Nechyba is professor of economics at Duke University in Durham, North Carolina, where he also serves as director of undergraduate studies for the Department of Economics. In addition, he is a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research, and he serves as associate editor for the American Economic Review and the Journal of Public Economic Theory. His research and teaching focus on the field of public economics, in particular primary and secondary education, federalism and the function of local governments, and public policy issues relating to disadvantaged families.
Professor Nechyba has lectured and taught in courses at the Lincoln Institute for several years, and he recently completed a working paper based on Institute-supported research, “Prospects for Land Rent Taxes in State and Local Tax Reform.” This conversation with Joan Youngman, senior fellow and chairman of the Institute’s Department of Valuation and Taxation, explores his interest in land taxation and his research findings.
Joan Youngman: How is a land tax different from a conventional property tax?
Thomas Nechyba: It’s really a question of tax efficiency. Any tax has two effects, which economists call the income and substitution effects. The income effect of a tax is the change in the choices made by the taxpayer because payment of the tax has reduced the taxpayer’s real income. The substitution effect arises because the very existence of the tax changes the relative prices of the taxed goods, and therefore gives an incentive to taxpayers to substitute non-taxed goods for taxed goods. The income effect does not give rise to any efficiency problems; it simply implies that some resources are transferred from taxpayers to the government, and we hope the government will do something useful with the money. But, the change in behavior from the substitution effect causes an economic distortion that does not benefit anyone. That is, when the higher price of a taxed good causes me to substitute to a different non-taxed good purely because of the distorted prices, then I am worse off and the government gets no revenue. This is the source of the loss of economic efficiency from taxation, because people are worse off than they were previously, and by a larger amount than the tax collections themselves. This phenomenon is sometimes called a deadweight loss.
Once I asked my students to react to the following statement on an exam: “People hate taxes because of income effects, but economists hate taxes because of substitution effects.” One student wrote that it was undeniably true because it showed that economists aren’t people! Well, I think at least some economists are also people. However, it is true that people dislike taxes primarily because they don’t like paying money to the government. Economists especially dislike those taxes that cause greater deadweight losses, i.e., taxes that have greater substitution effects.
A land tax is a very unusual tax. It does not carry this deadweight loss because it does not give rise to a substitution effect. No one can make a decision to produce more land or less land, and the fact that land is taxed will not distort economic decisions. If we think of the price of land as the discounted present value of future land rents, a tax that reduces expected future rents will cause the price of land to drop. But the total cost of the land, which is the purchase price plus the tax, remains unchanged. Those who are considering the purchase of land therefore face the same cost before and after the tax: before the tax, they simply pay a single price up front; after the tax, they pay a lower price up front but they know they will also have to pay all the future taxes. There is no substitution effect, only an income effect for those who currently own land, because now they can sell it for less than before. Property taxes that tax both land and buildings, on the other hand, do give rise to substitution effects because they distort the cost of making improvements to the property.
A revenue-neutral shift to land value taxation would reduce other, distortionary taxes. A shift to a more efficient tax can improve economic welfare without a loss in tax collections. This much is well known. What is not well known is the magnitude of this benefit and of the cost to landowners in terms of lower land prices. Conventional wisdom predicts that a shift to an efficient land tax would increase income and output but reduce land prices. This kind of general statement isn’t much help to policy makers. If one is suggesting major changes in a tax system, policy makers need to know whether the benefits and the costs are going to be large or small. My recent Lincoln Institute working paper, “Prospects for Land Rent Taxes in State and Local Tax Reform,” constructs a model of state economies in the U.S. to help us think about the effects of such changes.
JY: How did you become interested in developing an economic model for land taxation?
TN: A few years ago, Dick Netzer, professor of economics and public administration at New York University, suggested that I look at the implications for the U.S. economy of replacing capital taxes with land value taxes. Most economists know of the Henry George Theorem and recognize that land taxation is efficient, but they associate his ideas with nineteenth-century economic thought. We assume that all the changes in the economy since then, and changes in the economic role of land, have left these ideas inapplicable to contemporary tax systems. So I was quite surprised that my model indicated that substituting a land value tax for capital taxes on a national level would not only be efficient, as expected, but would actually raise the value of many types of land. However, property taxes are state and local taxes, and the U.S. constitution places special impediments to a national property tax, so a land tax would not be possible on a national level. Further, since each state economy is different, the results of substituting land value taxes for other taxes will also vary from state to state.
JY: How can a tax on land increase land prices?
TN: In and of itself, a tax on land does not increase land prices; it actually reduces land prices, because it reduces the discounted present value of land rents. My research does not consider a land value tax in isolation, but as part of a revenue-neutral tax reform that replaces other, distortionary taxes with a land value tax. Lower taxes on capital will increase capital usage, and more intensive use of capital will raise land prices. For example, if constructing a building becomes more profitable because the tax on the building is lowered or eliminated, an investor may be willing to pay a higher price for its components, including the land.
JY: How did you go about estimating the magnitude of these effects?
TN: I developed a general equilibrium model of an economy that uses land, man-made capital and labor in production. A general equilibrium model is one that examines how changes in one kind of market affect all other markets. This model is then applied to different states, as well as to one hypothetical “average” state, to see how various tax reforms that substitute land value taxes for taxes on capital or labor would affect prices and production. The division of capital into land and man-made capital is a departure from standard analysis, which generally looks at capital as a single category.
One critical element is the elasticity of substitution among these factors; that is, the ease with which one can be substituted for another. Technically, it is the percentage change in one factor that results from a 1 percent change in the other. This is the key to efficiency gains from reducing the tax on man-made capital and on labor and increasing the tax on land. A lower tax on man-made capital will increase the use of that capital, which in turn will produce greater output and more hiring of labor. The easier it is to substitute man-made capital and labor for land, the greater the benefit from a switch to land value taxation.
JY: Where do the elasticity numbers come from?
TN: I use a range of estimates drawn from the economic literature. For example, most studies of the substitution between capital and land give elasticity estimates between 0.36 and 1.13. My paper uses the relatively conservative estimates of 0.75, 0.5 and 0.25 as high, medium and low values, and looks at the result under each assumption. This number is then adjusted to reflect the amount of land in the state devoted to farming, on the assumption that farmland is less easily substituted for capital in the production process. I also ask similar questions with regard to substitution between land and labor.
The elasticities of the actual supplies of man-made capital and labor are also crucial. If taxes on them are reduced, how much extra capital and labor will be available as a result of the increased after-tax return? Often in studies of this sort we make what is called a “small open economy assumption.” We assume that the economy we are looking at is small in relation to the rest of the world, and that capital and labor flow freely into and out of the jurisdiction. In that case, the elasticity of supply is infinite. The opposite extreme would be an economy with the equivalent of closed borders, where no capital could enter or leave. In that case the elasticity of supply would be zero. In looking at U.S. states, the small open economy assumption is not completely accurate, and zero elasticity is not accurate either. The right number is somewhere in between. Neither capital nor labor is as mobile internationally as within the U.S., and labor in particular is less mobile across state boundaries than within a state or a small region. The small open economy assumption may be appropriate in some circumstances for smaller states, but we have to introduce more complex assumptions in other cases.
JY: How does your model compute taxes on land and labor and man-made capital? This isn’t a standard classification of taxes.
TN: This is complicated, because it involves payroll taxes, federal and state corporate taxes, federal and state income taxes, property taxes, sales taxes, and so on. So the model looks at all these taxes and makes assumptions about who is paying them to estimate an overall tax rate on labor from all sources—federal, state and local. Similarly, the model estimates an overall tax rate on land and on man-made capital. This allows us to move from an illustrative example in which taxes on labor and capital are replaced by land value taxes to considering changes in real-world taxes, which of course are never based solely on labor or capital.
JY: How do you represent the shift in taxes from labor and man-made capital to land?
TN: This is a hypothetical policy experiment in the model. Suppose, for example, you wanted to eliminate all sales taxes in a revenue-neutral way, making up the lost collections through a land value tax. Sales taxes are the average state’s largest revenue source, so this shift would be quite ambitious. The model shows what would happen under various elasticities of substitution and elasticities of supply, as described above. The tables in the paper show what land tax would be necessary to maintain revenue, and the changes in capital investment and land prices that would result.
JY: How do you move from the hypothetical average state to the 50 individual states?
TN: You have to begin by asking what factors might cause states to have different experiences with land value taxation. We consider each state’s taxes, because the benefits of shifting to a more efficient system will vary according to how much current taxes distort economic choices. Some states have no income taxes. Some states tax property heavily, while others tax sales heavily. The other critical component concerns the state’s sources of income—how they are divided among land, labor and man-made capital. The Bureau of Economic Analysis reports income from various sources by state, but does not account separately for income from land. For that information we draw on the Census of Agriculture data on the amount and market value of farmland to estimate an income figure.
JY: What kinds of results did you obtain?
TN: Since taxation of land is always economically efficient, and since taxation of other factors is always economically inefficient, a shift to land taxes always increases capital, income and labor use. For the “typical” state it seems that most of the simulated tax reforms are feasible, particularly those that reduce taxes on capital. A 20 percent cut in the sales tax, for instance, requires a nearly 24 percent increase in the tax on land, while a similar cut in property taxes requires virtually no change (0.2 percent) in the tax on land. Even a complete elimination of the state and local property tax calls for only a 23 percent increase in the tax on land, while an elimination of the sales tax would require a whopping 131 percent increase. Landowners would be deeply and adversely impacted by reforms that cut the sales tax (losing up to two-thirds of their wealth under a complete elimination of the sales tax), while they would barely feel the impact of most reforms focused on the property tax. They would experience at most a 7 percent decline in their wealth under the complete elimination of the property tax, and an actual increase in their wealth for less dramatic property tax reforms.
But these results differ substantially by state. For instance, the percentage change in the tax on land required to maintain constant state and local government revenues as taxes on capital are eliminated ranges from -1.91 percent to over 104 percent. Similarly, the impact on land prices varies greatly, with prices barely declining (or even increasing) in some states while falling by as much as 85 percent in others. While the elimination of all state and local taxes on capital is therefore technically feasible in all states, it is clearly politically more feasible in some states than in others. Overall, of course, replacing distortionary taxes with nondistortionary taxes on land always brings growth in the employment of capital and labor and increases output—but the size of these impacts also varies greatly. Given that the main political hurdle to land taxation is the expected adverse impact on landowners, these results seem to indicate that, as in the case of the “typical” state, such reforms should emphasize the simultaneous reduction in taxes such as the corporate income tax or the property tax.
JY: What do you take as the central lessons of this work?
TN: Several broad lessons emerge from the analysis of a typical state. First, elasticity assumptions are crucial to the exercise of predicting the likely impact of tax reforms. Second, under elasticity assumptions that are both plausible and relatively conservative, this model predicts that some types of tax reforms are more likely to succeed than others. In particular, tax reforms that reduce taxation of capital in favor of land taxation will have more positive general welfare implications while minimizing the losses to landowners. So policy makers might consider reforming corporate income and property taxes rather than sales and personal income taxes. Third, since elasticities tend to be lower in the short run, it is likely that some of the positive gains of tax reforms that reduce distortionary taxes in favor of land taxes will emerge only with time.
The most striking lesson from simulating tax reforms for the 50 different states is how greatly results can vary depending on underlying economic conditions and current tax policies in those states. Thus, far from arriving at “the answer” regarding the impact of land tax reforms, this study suggests that such answers are likely to differ greatly depending on the context in which the reforms are undertaken. Reforms that raise the tax on land are likely to be more effective the larger the size of the reform, the higher the initial distortionary taxes in the state, and the lower the current level of state income. And, reforms are more likely to be politically feasible (in the sense of not causing great declines in land values) when they involve reductions in taxes on capital.
The idea that land value taxation is unrealistic or would drive land prices into negative numbers is based on a static view of the economy, where no one responds to tax changes by substituting one factor for another. Once you accept that behavior will change in response to taxes, that static view no longer applies. Under these fairly conservative assumptions, tax reforms that use land taxes to eliminate entire classes of distortionary taxes are economically feasible in virtually all states. This work shows that, far from being quaint or outmoded, the idea of taxing land value is quite relevant to the contemporary policy debate.
Working Paper Information: Thomas Nechyba. 2001. “Prospects for Land Rent Taxes in State and Local Tax Reform.” 70 pages. The complete paper is posted on the Lincoln Institute website at www.lincolninst.edu and may be downloaded for free.
If cynics know the price of everything but the value of nothing, then they may have something in common with contemporary American planners. Constrained by the courts, the planning fraternity sometimes appears to have spent the last decade rationalizing nexuses and quantifying costs without really addressing the social and environmental values that should underpin the planning process. Under assault from those criticizing government, as well as from the property rights movement, the profession seems to have retreated into the land of that dismal science, economics. This allegation has been made in a number of ways over the past few years by critics as diverse as New Urbanist architects and, in England, the Royal Family. Is it really justified?
This article is written from an English perspective and is based on research into the types of planning tools used in the United States to minimize the adverse effects and costs of development or to maximize public benefits. The intention is to adapt the best American practices for future use in the United Kingdom.
A broad analysis of the types of policy processes presently being used highlights an amazing breadth and depth of local policy innovation. The accompanying table outlines the range of policies found, broken down either by the way they have been justified or the process that has been used. This “family” grouping may help in suggesting other types of policies that can be used to achieve similar goals. It may also provide a useful reminder that the policies are always supposed to achieve aims, and that those aims should always be in a constant state of review.
The policies span a wide range. Some are not traditionally thought of as land use or planning policies. Indeed, in many cases the policies are not promoted with any explicit intention of achieving specific land use goals. They are, however, all capable of directly affecting land use patterns and, properly used, can all realize benefits to the community.
Purpose Policies
Harm, quality of life and control policies are all well-accepted planning tools. They work to prevent development in inappropriate areas–on wetlands or in congested districts, for example–or to require development in certain places. For the most part these policies do not offer any new lessons to UK planners. However, their scope is widening. New harms are being defined, such as air quality, lack of public transit accessibility and effects on the water table.
In addition, new, more limited types of land interests, such as easements and deed restrictions, are being used as controls, and new actors are becoming involved. For example, in South Florida the Water Management District is now a major purchaser of land and development rights, working in loose alliance with planning authorities. School boards, forest preserve districts and private utility companies have also become more interventionist.
Nevertheless, the main areas of experimentation are in other family groups. Cost policies are being used more proactively and are being expanded in scope. Fees are being used to either encourage or discourage development in particular locations. In San Diego impact fees in outlying zones have been set at economically prohibitive levels to deter development. In Dade County, Florida, road impact fees are banded and fees increase towards the urban fringe. In Montgomery County, Maryland, certain fees are waived when affordable housing is provided.
Cost policies can also be used to raise revenue to meet off-site costs for nontraditional “infrastructure.” In Boston and San Francisco linkages have been identified between the construction of new offices and the need for housing, justifying the extraction of money sums. In principle the range of these fees could be expanded. The City of San Diego already charges developers for new libraries, fire stations and other community facilities, and includes some future maintenance costs. In rapidly growing areas, the public costs of new health infrastructure, hospitals and clinics might also be considered.
Some municipalities have considered the possibility of charging “disassociation fees” that recognize the cost to the community of development away from central cities. “Historic investment” or “recoupment” fees could account for the cost of past provision of infrastructure. In the case of schools or hospitals, a charge could also be made to reflect the cost of wasted desk and bed capacity in the area from which migration has occurred. Alternatively, fees could be charged for the “softer” social costs of increasing the distance that citizens need to travel to reach open space or to reflect the additional stress that occurs from lengthy journeys through strip development.
Process Policies
Market policies have been described as creating “a currency in the public domain that [can] then be traded.” Unsurprisingly, new markets have developed swiftly, responding to local conditions. These policies generally require zoning that sets limits on development at lower levels than the market would otherwise build. A release from that limitation can then be “sold” or transferred for use either on or off site. Seattle, New York state, Maryland and New Jersey lead the way with policies of this type, creating the necessary currency in the form of bonus floor areas and transferable rights. They also provide “market” infrastructure such as credit banks in some cases. In Florida the private sector has set up profitable “mitigation banks” that reclaim damaged land to create mitigation credits for future use by developers whose projects would threaten wetlands. Private sector sales of “utility credits” also occur.
Fiscal policies are all too often seen as intended simply to raise revenue. Yet they can also guide land uses and capture public benefits from increases in the development value of private land. In some Business Improvement Districts, such as those in Miami Beach and Chicago, increased tax assessment streams have been bonded and the proceeds spent on capital works achieving planning aims. In San Diego’s special assessment areas the cost of new social infrastructure, such as parks and libraries, is borne in this way.
In some areas it is possible to secure contributions towards public works that lead to private benefits, for example when major new transport links or services are provided. In downtown Miami, businesses that benefit from a transit system pay a property assessment that meets the county’s share of the original infrastructure cost.
The final two categories of policies are important for different reasons. Adequate transitionary policies are essential. Politically and legally it is difficult to introduce new policies unless careful attention is paid to minimizing or mitigating the immediate costs. Providing for a lengthy period of introduction, or providing compensating credits, as in Montgomery County, may offer some comfort. In some areas “reversionary” permits have been proposed, where development rights revert back to an earlier or less valuable use if they remain unimplemented for a period of time. The miscellaneous policies provide clear means for enforcement. All too often well-intentioned policies are not rigorously applied. Agreements may allow easier control and greater certainty.
Conclusion
It is clear that a large number of policy tools are available to and used by American planners. The opening criticism questioned their fixation with economics. While economic issues are and always should be part of the planning process, the scope of planning policies itself shows that planning is about more than economics. However, it has also become apparent that planners tend to use only a limited range of instruments, even when alternative approaches might better achieve their policy goals.
For a variety of legal and institutional reasons, municipalities understandably concentrate on those policies that they have already used and that have worked. Notwithstanding that, to an English planner the American system as a whole offers a mouthwatering array of policy feasts. It is a shame that so many planners operating within the system only nibble at the corners of a table that is groaning with the weight of possible delights.
Stephen Ashworth is a visiting fellow at the Lincoln Institute and a Harkness Fellow in a program sponsored by the Commonwealth Fund of New York. In the United Kingdom he is a partner in the firm of Denton Hall, Lawyers. This article is drawn from his research on “Harnessing Land and Development Values for Public Benefit.”
Una versión más actualizada de este artículo está disponible como parte del capítulo 7 del CD-ROM Perspectivas urbanas: Temas críticos en políticas de suelo de América Latina.
Los proyectos de reurbanización a gran escala (denominados grandes proyectos urbanos o GPU) plantean muchas dudas sobre las consecuencias de la urbanización subsiguiente provocada por la intervención. Los GPU se caracterizan por el impacto que tienen en una parte significativa de la ciudad, a menudo con el uso de algunos nuevos instrumentos fiscales o reguladores y la participación de una amplia red de agentes e instituciones. Se espera que estos proyectos afecten los precios del suelo, reciclen la infraestructura y las instalaciones existentes o creen otras nuevas, y atraigan otras construcciones nuevas.
Los GPU como instrumento de política urbana han sido objeto de controversia y debate considerable en toda América Latina. Se argumenta a menudo que promueven la exclusión social y la renovación de edificios para aspiraciones de la clase media, tiene efectos limitados en la estimulación de actividades inmobiliarias y requieren grandes subsidios públicos (a veces ocultos) que a menudo quitan recursos fiscales de otras necesidades urbanas. A pesar de su creciente popularidad en América Latina, existe poca evidencia empírica para apoyar estas críticas.
Este artículo presenta el caso de un GPU introducido en São Paulo, Brasil, en 1996 como una “operación urbana” para reurbanizar un área de ingresos medios que constaba en su mayor parte de hogares unifamiliares que iba a ser atravesada por la prolongación de la Avenida Faria Lima. El proyecto es conocido como el Consorcio de Operaciones Urbanas de Faria Lima (OUCFL). Examinamos los principios económicos que afectan el rendimiento fiscal del proyecto y su oportunidad para recuperar plusvalías, evaluamos los cambios en densidad residencial y analizamos los cambios en la distribución de ingresos y la estructura de la propiedad. Por último, ofrecemos algunas sugerencias de políticas sobre cómo y cuándo usar esta clase de instrumento en función de estas evaluaciones.
¿Qué es una operación urbana?
Una operación urbana es un instrumento legal que trata de proporcionar a los gobiernos locales el poder de llevar a cabo intervenciones relacionadas con mejoras urbanísticas y de planificación municipal en asociación con el sector privado. Identifica un área particular dentro de la ciudad que tenga el potencial de atraer inversiones inmobiliarias privadas para beneficiar a la ciudad en su totalidad. Los índices de planificación municipal apropiados (es decir, zonificación y otros reglamentos sobre coeficientes de construcción, índices de ocupación y usos del suelo) se redefinen según un plan maestro, y las inversiones se hacen en infraestructura nueva o reciclada.
Una operación urbana permite a la municipalidad recuperar (a través de medios negociados u obligatorios) los incrementos del valor del suelo relacionados con los subsiguientes cambios de uso del suelo. En comparación con otros instrumentos de recuperación de plusvalías, estos fondos están destinados o justificados dentro del perímetro del proyecto y serán compartidos entre el gobierno y el sector privado para inversiones en infraestructura urbana y subsidios de las inversiones inmobiliarias privadas para apoyar el proyecto mismo.
Cada operación urbana en Brasil es propuesta por el poder ejecutivo y aprobada por el poder legislativo de la jurisdicción. En el caso de São Paulo, esta autoridad fue creada en la Ley Orgánica Municipal (Constitución de la Ciudad) en 1990, que se incluyó más adelante en la nueva ley de urbanización brasileña (Estatuto de la Ciudad de 2001). Los primeros proyectos propuestos fueron la Operación Anhangabaú (más tarde ampliada como parte de la Operación Centro de la Ciudad y denominada Operación del Centro) y Água Branca, seguida por las operaciones de Água Espraiada y Faria Lima. Después de aprobar el nuevo Plan Maestro de la ciudad en 2001, se generaron otras nueve operaciones urbanas. Se espera que estos trece proyectos afecten del 30 al 40 por ciento del área edificable de la ciudad de São Paulo.
Financiación de Faria Lima
La operación urbana de Faria Lima (OUCFL) fue propuesta y aprobada en 1995 con el objetivo de obtener recursos privados para financiar las inversiones públicas necesarias para comprar suelo e instalar infraestructura con el fin de ampliar la Avenida Faria Lima. Se estimó que estos costos ascendían a aproximadamente US$150 millones, dos tercios para adquisición de suelo y un tercio para la avenida en sí. Al proyecto se opusieron muchos interesados por motivos que iban desde el origen de los fondos (es decir, avanzados del presupuesto local a través de una deuda nueva) hasta preocupaciones del vecindario (una de las cuales pudo mantener sin cambios los coeficientes de edificabilidad [floor area ratio o FAR] y excluirlos legalmente de la zonificación de OUCFL) y problemas de diseño técnico.
Los estudios técnicos realizados en su momento indicaban que sería posible aprovechar 2.250.000 metros cuadrados potenciales más de los ya permitidos por la legislación de zonificación de la ciudad y consecuentemente se modificaron los FAR. Estos derechos de construcción adicionales fueron garantizados contra un pago mínimo del 50 por ciento de su valor de mercado usando el instrumento existente Solo-Criado (venta de derechos de construcción). La OUCFL despertó gran interés por parte de empresarios inmobiliarios. No obstante, este instrumento también fue cuestionado por su falta de transparencia, su enfoque de “proyecto a proyecto”, y la arbitrariedad en la forma en que se establecieron precios relevantes que después se usaron para calcular el valor de los derechos de construcción adicionales.
En agosto de 2003 ya se había autorizado un total de 939.592 metros cuadrados, o casi el 42 por ciento de los 2.250.000 metros cuadrados totales posibles. Se aprobaron más de 115 proyectos inmobiliarios, incluidos casi el 40 por ciento de edificios comerciales y el 60 por ciento de edificios residenciales de alta calidad. No obstante, los recursos (aproximadamente US$280 millones) obtenidos de estos proyectos aprobados no habían compensado completamente los gastos (US$350 millones, incluidos el capital más los intereses) relacionados con la ampliación de la avenida, teniendo en cuenta los elevados intereses reinantes en Brasil durante los casi ocho años desde la ejecución de los gastos. Así, aproximadamente el 80 por ciento del costo (aunque mayor que el anticipado) se ha recuperado mediante el proceso de Venta de Derechos de Construcción. Desde julio de 2004, la compensación de estos fondos de avance se obtuvo mediante el ingenioso y nuevo mecanismo de recuperación de plusvalías conocido como CEPAC, siglas que significan Certificado de Potencial Adicional de Construcción. Un CEPAC representa un metro cuadrado.
La introducción de CEPAC
Aunque los CEPAC se definieron en el Estatuto de la Ciudad de 2001 de Brasil, no fueron aprobados por el CVM (equivalente brasileño de la Comisión de Bolsa y Valores de EE. UU.) como libremente comerciables en la Bolsa de Valores Brasileña hasta diciembre de 2003. El reglamento establece que el precio de cada certificado sea definido por una subasta pública y que puedan ejecutarse en cualquier momento los metros cuadrados correspondientes de derechos de construcción (que también incluyen cambios de uso e índices de ocupación) expresados en cada certificado. El reglamento indica también que se pueden emitir nuevos lotes de certificados (y venderse en subastas) sólo después de confirmarse que los recursos capturados por la venta previa han sido destinados de forma efectiva al proyecto. Para asegurar este uso designado, los ingresos se depositan en una cuenta especial, no en el tesoro municipal. Desde el punto de vista de los inversores privados, esta designación asegura la aceptabilidad de este instrumento de recuperación de plusvalías a su propia valorización. Al emitir un número menor de certificados que el número de derechos de construcción potenciales —es decir, al gestionar su escasez— el sector público puede beneficiarse de la valorización y poder así recuperar la plusvalía “ex-ante” (Afonso 2004, 39).
La aprobación final de los CEPAC para la OUCFL y todos los pasos necesarios para lanzarlos al mercado financiero se produjo a mediados de 2004, y la primera subasta a finales de diciembre de 2004 generó casi 10 millones de reales (unos US$4 millones), correspondientes a la venta de unos 9.000 CEPAC de un grupo autorizado de 650.000 metros cuadrados. Los certificados de OUCFL se vendieron a un valor nominal de 1.100 reales (unos US$450) por metro cuadrado sin un precio adicional como resultado del proceso de licitación.
Esta situación contrasta con la operación urbana de Água Espraiada, que se esperaba que fuera completamente financiada por CEPAC desde su inicio. En su tercera subasta, los certificados ya estaban alcanzando los 370 reales por certificado en vez del valor nominal de 300 reales fijado para esta operación. Una subasta más reciente en Água Espraiada vendió 56.000 CEPAC y alcanzó 21 millones de reales (US$9,5 millones), reflejando un precio por certificado de 371 reales. Este contraste de precios refleja los distintos valores nominales originales en los dos proyectos. En el caso de OUCFL los urbanizadores de compraron (y acumularon) derechos de construcción por adelantado, para beneficiarse de las reglas más flexibles antes de las aprobaciones de la CVM. El precio de los certificados en Faria Lima empezó siendo de más de 1.100 reales porque es un área más valorada. En Água Espraiada los urbanizadores estaban dispuestos a pagar un precio mayor que el valor nominal original, ya que los certificados eran menos caros y había una mayor demanda.
Implicaciones de los precios del suelo
Los precios del suelo sin ocupar y de las áreas urbanizadas experimentaron un aumento considerable en algunos bloques dentro del perímetro de OUCFL durante los años 90, pero disminuyó en otros bloques. No obstante, el precio promedio del metro cuadrado de nueva urbanización descendió en toda la región metropolitana de San Paulo (RMSP) en todas las franjas de precios, cuando se comparan los precios promedio de 1991 a 1996 con los de 1996 a 2000.
Después de controlar una serie de atributos relacionados con el carácter variable de las urbanizaciones y su ubicación, las estimaciones de precios mostraron un aumento relativo inequívoco después de haber dado comienzo a la operación. El precio promedio por metro cuadrado dentro del perímetro de OUCFL aumentó de 1.680 reales en el período de 1991–1996 a 1.920 reales en el período de 1996–2001, lo que representa un aumento del 14 por ciento, mientras que los precios en la RMSP disminuyeron de 1.210 a 1.060 reales, lo que representa un descenso del 12 por ciento en el mismo período (1,95 reales/1,00 dólares estadounidenses en diciembre de 2000). Así pues, el precio por metro cuadrado en OUCFL era aproximadamente un 26 por ciento mayor que el de RMSP. El precio por metro cuadrado en OUCFL fue un 38 por ciento mayor que el precio promedio en la RMSP en 1991–1996, y aumentó a un 81 por ciento en 1996–2001.
¿Fue este aumento capturado por la municipalidad el previsto? Considerando que el costo de la construcción es en promedio aproximadamente igual a 1.000 reales por metro cuadrado, la subasta de 2004 (la única hasta ahora) capturó casi todo el valor añadido a los precios actuales. El sistema previo anterior a CEPAC capturó aproximadamente el 50 por ciento o más, dependiendo de la capacidad y del éxito de los negociadores municipales, y de la exactitud del precio de referencia. CEPAC ahora cambia este porcentaje y el valor nominal del instrumento puede recuperar todo el incremento del valor o incluso más, dependiendo de la relación de este valor nominal con los precios del mercado, y de los resultados de futuras subastas. Al comparar un proyecto de reurbanización financiado completamente por bonos de construcción (como CEPAC) y otro financiado totalmente por tributos inmobiliarios generales, no existe ninguna duda de que el anterior es menos regresivo que este último. Incluso con un tributo inmobiliario progresivo, con tasas que aumenten según los valores, parte de los costos serían pagados por hogares más pobres.
Esta evidencia de que aproximadamente el 80 por ciento del costo del proyecto ya se ha recuperado, en combinación con la subasta de los derechos de construcción restantes mediante CEPAC y el impacto de la apreciación de la propiedad en los ingresos de tributos inmobiliarios actuales, indica que el proyecto no sólo debe pagarse por sí mismo sino que realmente genera una plusvalía fiscal para la ciudad en general en los siguientes cinco o siete años.
En efecto, los cambios causados al sustituir casas unifamiliares más antiguas por nuevos edificios residenciales y comerciales produjeron un cambio sustancial en la recaudación de tributos inmobiliarios en el área de la OUCFL. Muchas parcelas e incluso bloques enteros habían sido ocupados por casas de uno o dos pisos construidas en los años 50. Muchas de estas estructuras tenían derecho a un coeficiente de descuentos por obsolescencia de hasta un 30 por ciento del tributo inmobiliario. Fueron reemplazadas por edificios nuevos, más altos y de mayor calidad para los que el descuento era nulo. Nuestras estimaciones indican que las diferencias en recaudación de tributos inmobiliarios por metros cuadrados construidos puede haber aumentado al menos 2,7 veces y hasta 4,4 veces más. Es decir, el tributo inmobiliario promedio por metro cuadrado aumentó a un mínimo de 588,50 reales hasta un máximo de 802,50 reales desde 220,95 reales si la casa tenía más de 25 años, o desde 179,70 reales si la casa tenía más de 30 años.
Implicaciones sociales
El caso de la OUCFL ofrece una oportunidad única para cuantificar cambios en las características de residentes antes y después de la intervención, ya que hay datos disponibles a nivel de seguimiento del censo para 1991 y 2000, y la intervención empezó en 1996. Nuestro análisis de renovación y desplazamiento de residentes más pobres confirma principalmente las conclusiones de Ramalho y Meyer (2004) de que los ingresos promedio han aumentado relativamente en la mayoría de los bloques dentro del perímetro de la OUCFL. En lo que se refiere a las normas brasileñas, la clase media-alta fue desplazada de la región por el 5 por ciento más rico de hogares en el área metropolitana. Los datos del censo también mostraron que la densidad residencial descendió entre 1991 y 2000, de 27 a 22 residencias por hectárea, aunque estas cifras pueden estar distorsionadas porque reflejan la razón de residencias totales en todo el área, no un promedio de las razones por parcela donde se convirtió el uso del suelo.
Los datos de 1991 indicaron que la población ya estaba abandonando el área de la OUCFL antes de la aprobación de la operación urbana, pero este éxodo se intensificó después de 1996, generando parcelas desocupadas en el proceso de configuración del sitio para acomodar a las nuevas urbanizaciones de edificios altos. Al mismo tiempo, aumentó la densidad de construcción. El número promedio de pisos por nuevo edificio en el área aumentó de 12,6 en el período de 1985–1995 a 16,7 en el período de 1996–2001. El número de viviendas por edificio aumentó de 37,1 a 79,6 en los mismos períodos.
Esta contradicción aparente entre la menor densidad residencial y el mayor número de viviendas se explica en parte por la construcción de edificios comerciales que reemplazaron muchas residencias unifamiliares en parcelas pequeñas o de tamaño promedio. La OUCFL provocó una concentración inmobiliaria considerable, ya que los nuevos edificios comerciales y residenciales reemplazaron las casas y requirieron áreas de suelo más grandes para proyectos arquitectónicos de clase alta. Los 115 proyectos aprobados entre 1995 y agosto de 2003 que solicitaron aumentos en los coeficientes de utilización requerían un total de 657 parcelas, o un promedio de 5,7 parcelas por proyecto.
La combinación del aumento en nivel de ingresos y la reducción en densidad de hogares indican que el proceso de renovación avanzó dentro y fuera de la región de la OUCFL durante los años 90. No obstante, éste no es un caso clásico de renovación para la aspiración de clases medias, donde las familias pobres son expulsadas de un área debido a diversas presiones socioeconómicas. En este caso fueron mayormente las clases medias-altas quienes fueron desplazadas. Excepto en lo que se refiere al pequeño núcleo de favelados restantes (Favela Coliseu), la región estaba ya ocupada por personas que pertenecen a los sectores más ricos de la sociedad.
Algunas observaciones de política
Este artículo contribuye al debate sobre la gestión social de valoración del suelo proporcionando evaluaciones de datos reales y elementos económicos. Estos elementos faltaban en la mayoría de los análisis, y creemos que este vacío en las publicaciones ha contribuido a una interpretación incompleta de las implicaciones de una operación urbana y a recomendaciones de política pública equivocadas.
Nuestra conclusión es que el mecanismo de financiación de CEPAC por sí mismo no aumenta la característica regresiva de las operaciones urbanas, ya que sin esos bonos de derechos de construcción toda la inversión en reurbanizaciones sería financiada por impuestos generales. Si el proyecto de la OUCFL fuera inadecuado en términos de distribución de ingresos, hubiera sido aún peor sin el mecanismo de recuperación de plusvalías. En vez de eso, CEPAC y el mecanismo de recuperación de plusvalías usado previamente ofrecieron dos características deseables en cualquier inversión pública: cobrar a los nuevos terratenientes es al menos neutro en términos de distribución de ingresos; y los beneficiarios principales terminan por pagar el proyecto.
Además, el mecanismo de operación urbana ofrece incentivos para la reurbanización. Dado que la mayoría de los proyectos aumentan los precios del suelo y echan a los pobres de la región, sería mejor invertir todo el presupuesto municipal en proyectos a pequeña escala. Esto es lo opuesto a lo que ocurrió con la reurbanización de la rica área adyacente de Berrini donde los urbanizadores decidieron la forma de concentrar su inversión, resultando en una concentración aún mayor de ingresos que en el área de la OUCFL. Debido a la falta de acción de los gestores de política en ese caso, la municipalidad no capturó ningún valor de Berrini, pero pagó el costo completo de la infraestructura.
El uso de bonos de derechos de construcción puede disminuir el aspecto regresivo de la urbanización, pero hacer que un proyecto sea verdaderamente progresivo requiere atención en el lado de los gastos, financiando toda la inversión a través de instrumentos como CEPAC. La limitación principal sobre la distribución de beneficios a los pobres es que la ley establece que todos los fondos recogidos mediante la recuperación de plusvalías (CEPAC u otros instrumentos) deben invertirse dentro del perímetro de la intervención. Una forma de que estas intervenciones sean más progresivas es invertir en actividades que suministren extras a los pobres, como transporte público, educación y salud. Además, la legislación importante permite que la administración seleccione un área dentro del perímetro de una operación urbana y la declare zona especial de interés social (ZEIS) donde las parcelas se pueden usar exclusivamente para vivienda social de bajos ingresos.
Otra alternativa es establecer áreas de vivienda social dentro del perímetro de la operación urbana. Al subsidiar viviendas de bajos ingresos con dinero de urbanizadores y nuevos terratenientes, no habría una distorsión de precios fuera de la industria de la vivienda. El subsidio resulta de la segmentación del mercado y de la transferencia de la renta adicional a hogares pobres. Se trata de una gestión social real de valoración del suelo.
Ciro Biderman está afiliado al Centro de Estudios de Política y Economía del Sector Público (Cepesp) en la Escuela de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales de la Fundación Getúlio Vargas de São Paulo, Brasil. Es profesor visitante de desarrollo internacional y planificación regional en el Departamento de Estudios y Planificación Urbanos del Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge.
Paulo Sandroni es economista y profesor en la Escuela de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales de la Fundación Getúlio Vargas.
Martim O. Smolka es Senior Fellow y director del Programa sobre América Latina y el Caribe del Lincoln Institute.
Referencias
(Estas publicaciones sólo se encuentran en portugués).
Afonso, Luis Carlos Fernandes. 2004. Financiamento é desafio para governantes (La financiación es un desafío para los gobernantes). Teoria e Debate Nº 58, Mayo-Junio: 36–39.
Ramalho, T., e R.M.P. Meyer. 2004. O impacto da Operação Urbana Faria Lima no uso residencial: Dinâmicas de transformação (El impacto de la Operación Urbana Faria Lima en el uso residencial: dinámicas de transformación). Mimeo. São Paulo: Lume/FAUUSP.
Biderman, Ciro y Paulo Sandroni. 2005. Avaliação do impacto das grandes intervenções urbanas nos precos dos imoveis do entorno: O caso da Operação Urbana Consorciada Faria Lima (Evaluación del impacto de los precios en la propiedad cerca de intervenciones urbanas a gran escala: El caso del Consorcio de la Operación Urbana Faria Lima). Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Research Report (Abril).
¿De qué manera se verán afectadas las finanzas del gobierno municipal por la enorme y creciente carga de pagar los costos de pensión contraídos previamente? En particular, ¿de qué manera estos costos de pensión heredados cambiarán la percepción de los residentes respecto al impuesto municipal sobre la propiedad y su intención de pagarlo? como primer paso de un programa de investigación del lincoln institute of land policy mucho más amplio sobre estas cuestiones, cabe preguntarse: ¿Qué sabemos –e igualmente importante, qué no sabemos– acerca de la magnitud de las deudas por pensiones sin fondos del gobierno municipal en los estados unidos? (ver Gordon, rose y Fischer 2012).
Es un principio fundamental de las finanzas públicas que los servicios del presente deberían pagarse con ingresos del presente, y que el financiamiento de deudas debería reservarse para proyectos de capital que brinden servicios a los futuros contribuyentes. este principio se viola cuando las deudas por pensiones relacionadas con los servicios de los trabajadores en el presente no son financiadas con compras de activos financieros en el presente y, en su lugar, deben pagarlas los futuros contribuyentes.
Desafortunadamente, no siempre se observan los principios de la prudencia en las finanzas públicas, y los gobiernos municipales en los estados unidos han acumulado una importante cantidad de deudas por pensiones sin fondos en los últimos años. esta situación genera un quiebre en la importante relación entre los contribuyentes y los servicios que reciben: la correspondencia desigual entre el valor total de los servicios públicos y los recursos tomados del sector privado. existe un importante debate sobre la solidez de dicha correspondencia y cuánta es la similitud de la relación de precios entre el valor pagado y el valor recibido para los contribuyentes particulares; casi no quedan dudas de que utilizar los ingresos corrientes para pagar servicios prestados en el pasado debilita esta relación.
Una conciencia pública creciente
La cuestión de las pensiones para empleados del gobierno estatal y municipal aparece en los titulares casi a diario (recuadro 1). Hasta hace sólo unos pocos años, estas pensiones eran competencia casi exclusiva de unos pocos funcionarios elegidos, juntas designadas, asesores en inversiones, actuarios y agencias calificadoras de crédito. ¿Qué cambió? La respuesta más inmediata es la gran recesión, que condicionó no solamente los ingresos fiscales del estado sino también el valor de los activos de los planes de pensión. En particular, la tenencia de capital proveniente de fondos de pensión estatales y municipales perdió casi la mitad de su valor, ya que cayó del pico de US$2,3 billones alcanzado en septiembre de 2007 a sólo US$1,2 billones en marzo de 2009 (Junta de Gobernadores del Sistema de la Reserva Federal 2012).
———–
Recuadro 1: ¿En dónde se encuentran en peligro las pensione municipales?
A fin de comprender cuáles son los lugares donde las pensiones municipales estaban experimentando dificultades en particular, Gordon, Rose y Fischer (2012) utilizaron un software de monitoreo de medios de comunicación para realizar una investigación de todas las agencias de noticias nacionales de los EE.UU. durante los tres primeros meses de 2012. La búsqueda se centró en artículos que incluían la palabra “pensión” junto con otros términos que identificaban a los gobiernos municipales, como “municipalidad”, “ciudad” o “condado”, y descripciones de problemas de financiamiento, como, por ejemplo, “pasivo”, “déficit”, “sin fondos”, “recorte”, “mora”, “reforma” y “problema”. Los resultados de la búsqueda produjeron más de 2.000 artículos separados de diferentes lugares en todo el país.
Según este análisis, varios tipos de lugares están experimentando problemas con la cuestión de las pensiones. Un grupo lo forman las jurisdicciones que han estado perdiendo gente y empleos con el transcurso de los años. Uno de los ejemplos más notorios es Detroit, Michigan, en donde la cantidad de jubilados es el doble de los trabajadores activos. En esta categoría también entra la ciudad de Prichard, Alabama, que perdió más del 45 por ciento de su población desde 1970 y, el año 2010 tenía menos de 23.000 residentes. En septiembre de 2009, este municipio sencillamente dejó de enviar los cheques de pensión a sus exempleados y, un mes más tarde, se declaró en quiebra. Para dichas comunidades, los conflictos relacionados con las pensiones también pueden ser un síntoma de mayores problemas fiscales o de disfunciones políticas.
Otro grupo de jurisdicciones pasó del auge inmobiliario a el posterior derrumbe del mercado de la vivienda. Algunos ejemplos son las ciudades de rápido crecimiento en California, como Stockton, que este año se declaró en quiebra, siendo la ciudad más grande que se haya declarado en quiebra en la historia. Mucho más desconcertante es la situación de jurisdicciones relativamente acaudaladas, como los condados de Suffolk o Nassau, en Nueva York, que parecen no ser capaces de aplicar recortes estrictos en los gastos o aumentar los impuestos debido a la paralización política. En lugar de ello, muchas de estas jurisdicciones han recurrido al préstamo para cumplir con sus obligaciones de pago de pensiones.
Solamente dos de las recientes bancarrotas municipales (Vallejo, California, y Central Falls, Rhode Island) fueron resultado de presiones de las pensiones públicas y la compensación de empleados junto con una reducción de la recaudación. Otras jurisdicciones, como Harrisburg, Pensilvania, y el condado de Jefferson, Alabama, están en apuros debido a malas decisiones en las inversiones. Además, algunas ciudades importantes, como Atlanta, San Francisco y Nueva York, han tomado medidas para limitar el crecimiento de las pensiones, con frecuencia gracias a la cooperación de los sindicatos de empleados públicos municipales. Central Falls logró obtener concesiones de oficiales de policía y bomberos en activo, así como de jubilados, pero aun esta medida resultó insuficiente para detener la caída hacia la quiebra.
Aunque el mercado de valores se ha recuperado en gran medida y las tenencias de capital derivadas de planes estatales y municipales se han incrementado nuevamente a más de US$2 billones, las pensiones públicas siguen estando bajo estrecha vigilancia. Las agencias calificadoras de crédito están tomando cada vez más en cuenta las deudas por pensiones sin fondos a la hora de llevar a cabo sus evaluaciones de riesgo crediticio de los gobiernos estatal y municipal. Además, los analistas están haciendo oír cada vez más sus críticas sobre los métodos que comúnmente se utilizan para evaluar los niveles de financiamiento de las pensiones.
El gobierno federal también está prestando atención a este tema. El congreso, alarmado por la posibilidad de que los gobiernos entren en mora, celebró una serie de audiencias sobre las finanzas de los gobiernos estatal y municipal a principios de 2011. Hace poco, los miembros republicanos del comité conjunto económico (JEC, por sus siglas en inglés) emitieron informes en los que se vislumbraba el espectro de una crisis similar a la de la eurozona debido a las deudas por pensiones estatales sin fondos (JEC 2011; JEC 2012).
A la luz de estas críticas y de los motivos de preocupación en torno a los crecientes costos derivados de las pensiones, 43 estados promulgaron reformas importantes en sus sistemas de pensión entre 2009 y 2011 (Snell 2012). Las modificaciones más comunes fueron las siguientes: aumento de los requisitos en la aportación por parte de los empleados (30 estados), aumento de la edad y años de servicio para la elegibilidad (32), ajuste de fórmulas para calcular los beneficios (17), y reducción en los aumentos del costo de la vida (21). En algunos estados, las modificaciones se aplicaron solamente a los nuevos empleados, aunque en otros estados, estos cambios afectaron a los trabajadores activos y a los ya jubilados. Estas medidas han generado una gran controversia y han dado como resultado el inicio de juicios en colorado, Minnesota, Nueva Jersey y Dakota del Sur.
La mayor parte de esta creciente atención hacia las pensiones de empleados del gobierno se ha concentrado en los planes del gobierno estatal, mientras que las pensiones de empleados públicos municipales relativamente no han sido sometidas a análisis. Aunque los planes municipales representan un porcentaje modesto del total de afiliados a las pensiones públicas (10 por ciento) y del total de activos de pensiones públicas (18 por ciento), su quiebra puede ser devastadora. Los residentes y las empresas con posibilidades de mudarse podrían abandonar aquellas comunidades en las que se aplican impuestos altos para reconstruir los activos derivados de pensiones en lugar de brindar servicios básicos. Una base imponible reducida podría empeorar aún más el fondo, con menos posibilidades de pagar los beneficios prometidos. El resultado podría ser el surgimiento de más ciudades como Prichard, Alabama.
Una mirada conjunta a los planes de pensión estatales y municipales
Las pensiones estatales y municipales son una parte importante del sistema de jubilación de la nación. La figura 1 muestra la distribución del total de us$15,3 billones en activos para la jubilación a finales de 2011 por tipo de plan. Los fondos de jubilación de empleados públicos estatales y municipales poseían, en conjunto, us$2,8 billones en activos, o casi un quinto del total.
Todos los estados tienen al menos un plan de pensión para empleados públicos y, en algunos estados, varios planes. Existen más de 220 planes estatales (algunos de los cuales son planes gestionados por el estado que ofrecen cobertura a trabajadores del gobierno municipal) y cerca de 3.200 planes municipales (tabla 1). En total, estos planes dan cobertura a 14,7 millones de trabajadores, 8,2 millones de beneficiarios actuales y 4,8 millones de personas elegibles para obtener beneficios en el futuro pero que aún no los reciben.
Las pensiones estatales y municipales son importantes, además, porque el 27,5 por ciento de los empleados de gobierno no está integrado en el seguro social (Nuschler, Shelton y Topoleski 2011). Estos empleados públicos sin cobertura se encuentran concentrados en unos pocos estados. La figura 2 ofrece una clasificación de los 16 estados que presentan las mayores concentraciones de trabajadores gubernamentales sin cobertura del seguro social. Casi todos los empleados de gobierno, tanto estatal como municipal, de Ohio y Massachusetts y más de la mitad de los empleados públicos estatales y municipales de Nevada, Louisiana, Colorado, California y Texas no están cubiertos por el seguro social.
Otra característica fundamental de las pensiones estatales y municipales reside en que, en su mayoría, consisten en planes de beneficios definidos (DB, por sus siglas en inglés). Los beneficios se calculan utilizando una fórmula que, por lo general, sigue este patrón:
(Salario promedio de los 3 últimos años) x
(Años de servicio) x
(2 por ciento por cada año de servicio) =
Beneficios
La mayoría de las pensiones de gobierno estatal y municipal también incluyen un ajuste según el costo de la vida. Una minoría de trabajadores del sector público se encuentra inscrita en planes de aportes definidos (DC, por sus siglas en inglés), según los cuales se coloca un monto específico en un fondo de jubilación por cada año de trabajo. Si se las compara con los planes dc, las pensiones dB protegen a los empleados de los riesgos derivados de inversiones, inflación y longevidad. Hasta el año 2009, cerca del 80 por ciento de los trabajadores estatales y municipales se encontraba inscrito en planes DB, y sólo poco más del 20 por ciento de los empleados estatales y municipales estaba en planes DC. Los trabajadores del sector privado presentaban la composición opuesta: el 20 por ciento estaba inscrito en planes DB y el 80 por ciento, en planes DC (Oficina de Estadísticas Laborales de los EE.UU. 2011).
Los planes DB predominaban en el sector privado, pero han ido desapareciendo, en parte debido a que la Ley de Seguridad de Ingresos de Jubilación para Empleados de 1974 (ERISA, por sus siglas en inglés) impuso normas mínimas de financiamiento y estableció el requisito de realizar aportaciones para seguros y otras cargas administrativas en relación con estos planes.
La menor cantidad de requisitos de financiamiento y de presentación de reportes que se aplican a las pensiones públicas permite a los gobiernos trasladar los costos de los trabajadores al futuro. Esta es una forma implícita de pedir préstamos, ya que se pueden evadir las normas presupuestarias calculadas y evitar la aprobación del electorado que generalmente se requiere para emitir bonos.
Requisitos de financiamiento y de presentación de reportes para las pensiones estatales y municipales
Históricamente, la mayoría de las pensiones estatales y municipales se financiaron con recaudaciones generales a plazo. La práctica actual de prefinanciar los planes de pensión estatales y municipales comenzó en las décadas de 1970 y 1980. Aunque los planes del sector público no se encontraban sujetos a la ERISA, esta ley sí requería emitir informes sobre sus prácticas. El informe de 1978 indicaba un “alto nivel de ceguera sobre el costo de las pensiones (…) debido a la falta de valuaciones actuariales, la utilización de suposiciones actuariales irreales y la ausencia general de normas actuariales” (Munnell y otros 2008, 2).
Esta señal de alarma llevó a varios planes a incrementar voluntariamente los niveles de financiamiento y prestar más atención a las normas actuariales y contables. En 1984 se creó la Junta de Normas Contables del Gobierno (GASB, por sus siglas en inglés), que emitió las primeras normas para planes de pensión en 1986 y realizó una profunda revisión de sus normas de valuación actuarial en 1994. El cumplimiento de dichas normas es de carácter voluntario, pero tiene el reconocimiento de las agencias calificadoras de crédito, los auditores y otros profesionales encargados de recopilar datos. A diferencia de las normas de la ERISA, que requieren métodos de valuación específicos para todos los planes privados, la GASB establece criterios que permiten cierta flexibilidad en la utilización de métodos específicos por parte de los planes públicos. En consecuencia, existen serios motivos de preocupación en lo referente a la transparencia y la comparabilidad de los datos sobre los que informan los propios planes de pensión estatales y municipales en relación con sus deudas.
Aportaciones de los empleadores
El cálculo del Pasivo Actuarial Devengado (AAL, por sus siglas en inglés) de un plan requiere la siguiente información: edad e historial salarial de los afiliados; proyecciones de incremento salarial, edades de jubilación, ganancias por activos e inflación; tablas de probabilidad de longevidad; y una tasa de descuento para convertir valores futuros estimados en valores en curso. El Pasivo Actuarial Devengado Sin Fondos (UAAL, por sus siglas en inglés) es equivalente al AAL menos los activos del plan.
El “costo normal” de un plan de pensión es el aumento del AAL debido al año de servicio en curso de los empleados existentes. La ERISA requiere que el costo normal se salde con las aportaciones de los empleados y empleadores. La GASB especifica una “Aportación Anual Obligatoria” (ARC, por sus siglas en inglés) de costo normal más una amortización a 30 años del UAAL. El problema reside en que, contrariamente a lo que su nombre indica, en la mayoría de las jurisdicciones no es obligatorio el pago del ARC.
Elección de la tasa de descuento
La cuestión que recientemente ha recibido más atención es la elección de la tasa de descuento. Las normas actualmente aplicables de la GASB permiten el descuento de las deudas futuras en base al rendimiento por inversiones proyectado, lo que dio un promedio del 8 por ciento anual antes de la recesión. No obstante, la mayoría de los economistas y especialistas en teoría financiera estarían de acuerdo con Brown y Wilcox (2009, 538) cuando afirman que “la tasa de descuento utilizada para valuar las futuras deudas derivadas de las pensiones debería reflejar el grado de riesgo de dichas deudas”, no de los activos. Las garantías constitucionales y legales consideran a las pensiones gubernamentales de bajo riesgo, mientras que el rendimiento histórico por inversiones incluye una prima de riesgo.
Los gobiernos estatales y municipales no pueden evitar los riesgos a largo plazo, como son una prolongada caída en la productividad o una caída de la bolsa durante una década. Por lo tanto, la tasa histórica de rendimiento a largo plazo en una cartera con gran composición patrimonial (antes de aplicar ajustes por riesgos) resulta una tasa de descuento demasiado alta. Las tasas de descuento más altas pueden hacer que las pensiones parezcan tener mayores fondos que los que verdaderamente poseen. Esto reduce los requisitos de aportaciones e impone obligaciones sin garantía a los futuros contribuyentes si no se logran las altas tasas de rentabilidad. Lo que resulta aún peor es que los administradores de los planes tienen de esta manera un incentivo para buscar carteras de alto riesgo con el fin de obtener una mayor tasa de descuento y un menor ARC.
Existen sólidos argumentos a favor de que la tasa de descuento del 8 por ciento que utitilizan muchos de los planes de pensión pública es demasiado alta, aunque existe un consenso menor en lo que respecta a cuánto debería reducirse dicha tasa para ser apropiada. En lugar de analizar estos puntos de vista, obtuvimos una estimación del impacto que podría tener una tasa más baja. Munnell y otros (2012) calculan los posibles cambios que se producirían en las deudas reportadas si en todos los planes se utilizara una tasa de descuento del 5 por ciento, en lugar del 8 por ciento. Dichos autores estiman que las deudas estatales y municipales aumentarían de US$3,6 billones a US$5,4 billones, y que las proporciones de financiamiento totales (activos/AAL) disminuirían de 75 por ciento a sólo 50 por ciento. Este es un cambio enorme, ya que representa el doble de las deudas sin fondos (UAAL = AAL – activos).
Últimas modificaciones en las normas de la GASB
La GASB (2012) emitió nuevas normas contables que entrarán en vigencia en 2013 y 2014. Según la modificación principal, los gobiernos estatales y municipales deberán aplicar diferentes tasas de descuento sobre las partes de las deudas que tienen fondos y las que no los tienen. Se seguirá aplicando una tasa basada en los ingresos en la parte del pasivo que posea financiamiento, mientras que se utilizará una tasa más baja y sin riesgos respecto del UAAL. El impacto de este cambio sobre el pasivo reportado depende de cuántos fondos tenga un plan: los planes totalmente financiados no sufrirán modificación alguna, los planes con fondos suficientes experimentarán unos pocos cambios, y los planes con escasos fondos estarán sujetos a grandes aumentos en las deudas reportadas y reducciones en el financiamiento. Según las nuevas normas, los estados contables del gobierno deberán incluir el UAAL, lo que incrementará la visibilidad del pasivo sin fondos para el electorado.
¿Qué sabemos sobre las pensiones municipales?
A pesar de los crecientes motivos de preocupación respecto a la salud fiscal de los planes de pensión municipales, no se tiene un conocimiento sistemático de los mismos. La mejor información disponible proviene de la Encuesta Anual de Sistemas de Jubilación para Empleados Públicos Estatales y Municipales, llevada a cabo por la Oficina del Censo de los EE.UU. (2012). Cada cinco años se ofrece información detallada sobre cada organismo de gobierno. Cada año se da información de datos a nivel de planes para una muestra que incluye casi la mitad de los 3.200 planes municipales, y estos datos se utilizan para generar estimaciones de totales para cada estado por tipo de gobierno. Las tablas 1 y 2 muestran ejemplos de los tipos de información que presenta la encuesta.
Las principales virtudes de la encuesta sobre jubilaciones de empleados de la Oficina del Censo son la calidad de los datos y el hecho de que son exhaustivos. Una desventaja importante es la falta de relevancia temporal, ya que los últimos datos municipales disponibles son los correspondientes al ejercicio de 2010. Otro problema reside en que hace muy poco que la Oficina comenzó a informar acerca de las deudas de los planes, y sólo incluye estos datos respecto de los planes estatales. Al igual que otras fuentes de datos sobre pensiones, la Oficina del Censo no recaba información sobre los planes DC u otros beneficios posteriores al empleo (OPEB, por sus siglas en inglés).
No obstante, la encuesta sobre jubilación de empleados arroja cierta luz sobre las pensiones municipales. Por ejemplo, la cantidad de planes municipales por estado varía significativamente: 7 estados no poseen planes municipales, 20 estados tienen menos de 10, Florida e Illinois tienen más de 300 cada uno, y Pensilvania posee más de 1.400. La cantidad de afiliados activos por beneficiario es una medida rudimentaria para saber de qué manera los aportes de los empleados sirven para financiar el plan. La tabla 1 muestra que el promedio nacional en los planes municipales es de 1,4 trabajadores por jubilado, aunque la variación entre estados es considerable. Esta proporción de respaldo es menor que 1 en 12 estados; de entre 1 y 2 en 31 estados; y de más de 2 en 7 estados (Utah posee la proporción más alta: 6,8).
Ninguno de estos datos nos dice cuán suficientemente financiadas se encuentran las pensiones municipales. Para obtener esta información, debemos recurrir a encuestas independientes. La mayoría de estas encuestas ofrecen una buena cobertura sobre los planes estatales, aunque, por lo general, incluyen sólo información sobre algunos de los planes municipales más grandes, como, por ejemplo, la encuesta anual de planes de afiliados de la Asociación Nacional de Administradores de Jubilación Estatal (NASRA, por sus siglas en inglés). Unas pocas investigaciones nacionales se han centrado en las deudas por pensiones municipales, en lugar de estatales. Por ejemplo, Novy-Marx y Rauh (2011) analizan las finanzas de las pensiones municipales utilizando datos de los Informes Financieros Anuales Consolidados (CAFR, por sus siglas en inglés) respecto de los planes de ciudades y condados que poseen más de US$1.000 millones en activos a partir de 2006.
El Centro de Investigaciones sobre Jubilación (CRR, por sus siglas en inglés) de la universidad Boston College mantiene una Base de Datos de Planes Públicos (PPD) para los mayores planes estatales y municipales, con datos provenientes de informes actuariales individuales sobre los planes y CAFR del gobierno municipal. Mediante el uso de la PPD más otros tipos de información sobre planes municipales adicionales, el CRR recientemente emitió un informe con datos para 2010 en base a una muestra de 97 planes en 40 estados (Munnell y otros 2011). Esta es una muestra modesta en relación con el total de 3.200 planes municipales; no obstante, debido a que se concentra en los planes grandes, cubre el 59 por ciento de los activos de pensiones municipales y el 55 por ciento de los afiliados.
Un resultado importante de esta investigación es la amplia dispersión que existe en la relación promedio de financiamiento del 77 por ciento en 2010 (figura 3). De los 95 planes grandes de la muestra del CRR con información utilizable, sólo 16 poseían activos para cubrir más del 90 por ciento del pasivo. En el extremo opuesto, hay 9 planes con un financiamiento menor al 50 por ciento (Munnell y otros 2011). Además, este estudio muestra al ARC como un porcentaje de la nómina gubernamental municipal. El promedio general para 2010 es del 22 por ciento, y en este caso también existe una amplia dispersión (figura 4). De los 91 planes grandes en la muestra del CRR con información utilizable, más de la mitad (49) tienen un ACR por debajo del 20 por ciento de la nómina, aunque 16 planes poseen participaciones en el rango menos manejable de entre 30 por ciento y 80 por ciento. Cinco planes poseen un pasivo por pensiones de tal magnitud que, de pagarse por completo, costaría más que el 100 por ciento de la nómina.
Debe tenerse en cuenta que los gobiernos municipales en la mayoría de los estados no están obligados a pagar la cantidad total de ARC . No poseemos datos a nivel municipal; sin embargo, según un informe a nivel estatal, existe una amplia variación en el porcentaje de los ARC efectivamente pagados en todos los planes, todos los años y en todos los estados (Equipo de Trabajo para la Crisis Presupuestaria Estatal 2012). Munnell y otros (2011) calculan los pagos de pensión efectivamente realizados como un porcentaje de los presupuestos municipales, y en este caso también obtienen como resultado una variación considerable: el 14 por ciento de los gobiernos de la muestra destinan más del 12 por ciento de sus presupuestos al pago de las pensiones.
Conclusiones
Las pensiones del gobierno municipal se encuentran, en promedio, significativamente escasas de fondos. La razón fundamental reside en que, ante la falta de una obligación legal, muchos gobiernos no han reservado los suficientes fondos cada año para cubrir las deudas por pensión adicionales contraídas en ese año, y mucho menos para amortizar el pasivo sin fondos de años anteriores. En efecto, estos gobiernos piden préstamos para pagar los servicios de los trabajadores en el presente y trasladar la carga a futuros contribuyentes.
Tenemos muchos menos datos acerca de los 3.200 planes administrados a nivel municipal que los que tenemos sobre los 220 planes estatales. La mejor información respecto de los planes municipales proviene de investigadores que analizan los informes financieros detallados de los planes y los gobiernos municipales. Forzosamente, estos estudios se concentran en los planes más grandes. Lo que sí sabemos es que existe una amplia variación entre los diferentes planes respecto de ciertas medidas clave: el porcentaje del pasivo que se encuentra cubierto por los activos; la aportación completa que debería cubrir tanto los costos de pensión del año en curso como la amortización del pasivo sin fondos (ARC ) relativo a la nómina o a la recaudación anual; el porcentaje del ARC que se paga efectivamente; y el porcentaje del presupuesto en curso que se destina a los costos de pensión. Una importante cantidad de gobiernos municipales está en dificultades por una o más de estas medidas.
Lo que empeora aun más la situación es que lo que sabemos acerca del pasivo proviene de los datos reportados por los propios municipios y la tasa de descuento que estos gobiernos eligen. En casi todos los casos, la tasa de descuento es inadecuadamente alta, y la utilización de una tasa de descuento menor podría aumentar el pasivo sin fondos a más del doble. El resultado es un grave problema con respecto a las deudas por pensiones municipales que amenaza las finanzas del gobierno municipal, aunque no conocemos su magnitud ni el nivel de desigualdad de su distribución.
Sobre los autores
Richard F. Dye es visiting fellow del Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Asimismo es profesor en el Instituto de Gobierno y Relaciones Públicas de la Universidad de Illinois en Chicago, y profesor emérito de Economía en el Lake Forest College.
Tracy Gordonfellow en Estudios Económicos en el Instituto Brookings, Washington, DC. Su campo de investigación se centra en las finanzas públicas estatales y municipales, la economía política y la economía urbana.
Referencias
Brown, Jeffrey R. y David W. Wilcox. 2009. Discounting state and local pension liabilities. American Economic Review 99(2): 538–542.
Comité Económico Conjunto (Joint Economic Committee o JEC). 2011. States of bankruptcy, part I: The coming state pensions crisis. Republican Staff Commentary, Washington, DC, 8 de diciembre.
Comité Económico Conjunto (Joint Economic Committee o JEC). 2012. States of bankruptcy, part II: Eurozone, USA?. Republican Staff Commentary, Washington, DC, 15 de mayo.
Equipo de Trabajo para la Crisis Presupuestaria Estatal. 2012. Informe del Equipo de Trabajo para la Crisis Presupuestaria Estatal. http://www.statebudgetcrisis.org/wpcms/wp-content/images/Report-of-the-State-Budget-Crisis-Task-Force-Full.pdf.
Gordon, Tracy M., Heather M. Rose e Ilana Fischer. 2012. The state of local government pensions: A preliminary inquiry. Documento de trabajo. Cambridge MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Junta de Gobernadores del Sistema de la Reserva Federal. 2012. Flow of funds accounts of the United States, 7 de junio. http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/data.htm.
Junta de Normas Contables del Gobierno (Governmental Accounting Standards Board o GASB). 2012. GASB Improves Pension Accounting and Reporting Standards. Comunicado de prensa. 25 de junio. http://www.gasb.org/cs/ContentServer?c=GASBContent_C&pagename= GASB/GASBContent_C/GASBNewsPage&cid=1176160126951.
Munnell, Alicia H., Jean-Pierre Aubry, Josh Hurwitz y Laura Quimby. 2011. An update on locally administered pension plans. Resumen de políticas del Centro de Investigaciones sobre Jubilaciones de Boston College, julio.
Munnell, Alicia H., Jean-Pierre Aubry, Josh Hurwitz y Laura Quimby. 2012. The funding of state and local pensions: 2011–2015. Resumen de políticas del Centro de Investigaciones sobre Jubilaciones de Boston College, mayo.
Munnell, Alicia H., Kelly Haverstick, Steven A. Sass y Jean-Pierre Aubry. 2008. The miracle of funding by state and local pension plans. Resumen de políticas del Centro de Investigaciones sobre Jubilaciones de Boston College, abril.
Novy-Marx, Robert y Joshua Rauh. 2011. The crisis in local government pensions in the United States. En Growing old: Paying for retirement and institutional money management after the financial crisis. Editado por Robert Litan y Richard Herring, 47–74. Washington, DC: Instituto Brookings.
Nuschler, Dawn, Alison M. Shelton y John J. Topoleski. 2011. Social Security: Mandatory coverage of new state and local government employees. Servicio de Investigaciones del Congreso, julio. http://www.nasra.org/resources/CRS%202011%20Report.pdf.
Oficina de Estadísticas Laborales de los EE.UU. 2011. Employee benefits survey, retirement benefits: access, participation, and take-up rates. Marzo.
Oficina del Censo de los EE.UU. 2012. 2010 annual survey of state and local public employee retirement Systems. http://www.census.gov/govs/retire.
Snell, Ronald K. 2012. State pension reform, 2009–2011. Washington, DC: Consejo Nacional de Legislaturas Estatales, marzo.
More than any other single variable, the change in land values across time and over space provides important insights into the shifting spatial structure of a city. Whereas a typical property sale reflects the combined value of the land and buildings, the land value alone represents the actual current worth of a location and suggests expectations about the future. Even if a parcel bears the burden of an outmoded construction, the price of the land reflects the present discounted value of the stream of returns that could be earned from the highest and best use of the parcel. Rapidly rising land prices in an area of a city are a clear indication that people expect the neighborhood to be in high demand for some time to come, signaling investment opportunities to developers. Changes in land values may also serve to alert city officials that an area may require zoning changes and investments in infrastructure.
Land value is also an important component in the cost approach to property assessment, which is one of the three commonly used assessment methods (including the sales comparison and income approaches). The cost approach has three major components: (1) the cost of building the existing structure if it were new at the time of assessment; (2) the depreciation of the building to its current condition; and (3) the price of the land parcel. Adding (1) to (3) and subtracting (2) generally produces a good estimate of overall property value. In standard property transactions, however, land values are not easily separated from the value of structures. Sales of vacant land, which more clearly indicate a site’s value, are relatively rare in large, built-up urban areas; as a result, relatively few studies of vacant land sales exist (see Ahlfeldt and Wendland 2011; Atack and Margo 1998; Colwell and Munneke 1997; Cunningham 2006). Teardowns can sometimes be used to measure land values, because land represents the entire value of a property when the existing building is demolished immediately following a sale (McMillen 2006; Dye and McMillen 2007). However, teardowns tend to be concentrated in certain high-value neighborhoods, and the data on demolitions can be hard to obtain.
Among U.S. cities, Chicago is uniquely fortunate to have a data source, Olcott’s Land Values Blue Book of Chicago, which reported estimates of land values for every city block and for blocks in many Cook County suburbs for most of the 20th century. Olcott’s provided a critical input to the cost assessment procedure: After determining the building cost and depreciation, the overall value of a property can be assessed by multiplying the parcel size by the land value provided in the Blue Book series. This article is based on a sampling of data from the Olcott volumes (box 1). It includes a series of maps that provide a clear picture of the spatial evolution of Chicago during the 20th century, similar in spirit to the classic book, One Hundred Years of Land Values in Chicago (Hoyt 1933).
————————
Box 1: Data Sources for Chicago Land Values
Olcott’s Land Values Blue Book of Chicago covers the City and much of suburban Cook County with a series of 300 maps, each printed on one page of a book. The city itself comprises 160 individual maps with an impressive level of detail. Most block faces have a value representing the price per square foot for a standard 125-foot-deep lot. Land use is also indicated. Large lots and most industrial land have prices quoted by the acre or occasionally by the square foot for an unspecified lot depth. The data represent land values for 1/8- x 1/8-mile square grids, which closely follow Chicago’s street layout and thus resemble city blocks. Each year’s data set includes 43,324 observations for the entire city.
The Lincoln Institute of Land Policy has provided funding to digitize the data contained in Olcott’s Blue Book for a series of years spanning much of the twentieth century: 1913, 1926, 1932, 1939, 1949, 1961, 1965, 1971, 1981, and 1990. A more thorough description of the procedure used is presented in Ahlfeldt et al. (2011). Digitizing the maps involves bringing them into a GIS environment. Average land values are calculated for 1/8- x 1/8-mile squares overlaid on the maps. The full data set has more than 600,000 data points across the 10 individual years.
Olcott’s stopped publication in the early 1990s, and the last year of digitized data is 1990. To supplement Olcott’s records for recent years, the authors obtained data on all vacant land sales in the city from 1980 to 2011. More than 16,000 sales were successfully geocoded, and they display the dramatic increase in land prices during the period prior to the collapse of the housing market at the end of 2006. These combined data sets provide a unique opportunity to analyze the changing spatial structure of an entire city over an extended time.
————————
Spatial Variation in Land Values
Despite its flat terrain, Chicago has never been a truly monocentric city. Lake Michigan has long been an attractive amenity for its scenic value, its moderating effect on the climate, and the series of parks lining its shore. The Chicago River also has had a significant influence on the location of both businesses and households. Development to the north of the Central Business District (CBD) was delayed because the bridges over the main branch of the river had to open so often for river traffic that commuting to the Loop business area was unpredictable and time consuming. The north and south branches of the river attracted both industrial firms and low-priced residential developments for laborers while repelling high-priced homes designed for CBD workers. The locations of major streets, highways, and train lines also had significant effects on development patterns. Thus, there is ample reason to expect that the rate of change in land values varies across the city.
The maps in figure 1 show this spatial variation in land values in Chicago over time. In 1913, land values were highest in a large area around the CBD, and they were also quite high along the lakefront and along some of the major avenues and boulevards leading out of the downtown area. In 1939, this pattern was generally similar, along with the rise of the north side relative to the south side of the city: Land values were very high all along the northern lakefront and extending well inland on the north side. The area at the edge of the city due west of the CBD (the Austin neighborhood) also had relatively high land values in 1939.
By 1965, the pattern of land values had changed markedly. Very high land values were confined to a relatively small area in the CBD. The high-value area of the west-side Austin neighborhood was much smaller in 1965 than in 1939, and nearly all the formerly high-value areas had shrunk in size.
By 1990, however, the situation changed dramatically. The area with very high values extended much farther north and inland than previously. Areas on the south side had relatively high land values in 1990, particularly around the South Loop (near the CBD) and Hyde Park (along Lake Michigan south of the CBD).
After 1990, the pattern of continued redevelopment of the city is based on an analysis of actual sales of vacant land. The expansion of the high-value area to the north and west of the CBD is remarkable, and the near south side also enjoyed a resurgence during this time.
Figure 2 addresses how the recent recession affected the growth of land values in Chicago by expressing land values as a function of distance from the CBD. The plots show the change in average (log) land values over time for tracts with centroids falling within 2-, 5-, and 10-mile rings around the CBD. In 1913, average land values were far lower 10 miles from the CBD than in the closer rings. By the 1960s, there was little difference between land values across these distances. Since then, average values grew much more in the 2-mile ring than in more distant locations. During the Great Recession, land values declined rapidly in the 2-mile ring, less rapidly in the 5-mile ring, and not at all in the 10-mile ring. Thus, the areas that had the highest rates of appreciation during the period of extended growth also had the highest rates of decline during the recession.
Figure 3 provides a different perspective on the spatial variation in land values over time. The three panels show smoothed land value surfaces for 1913, 1990, and 2005. The 1913 and 1990 surfaces are estimated using Olcott’s data, while the 2005 estimates are based on sales of vacant land. In all three years, land values are far higher in the CBD than elsewhere. In 1913, there are a large number of local peaks in land values at the intersections of major streets. These areas were relatively small commercial districts that served local residents in a time before car ownership was commonplace. In 1990, the land value peak in the CBD is accompanied by a much lower plateau just to the north along the lakefront. In 2005, the plateau has grown to a large area that extends well into the north side and inland along the lakefront. The region of high land values has also extended south along the lakefront, with a local rise much farther south in Hyde Park.
Persistence of Spatial Patterns
Historical land values are interesting not only because they reveal how an urban area has changed over time, but also because the past continues to exert substantial influence on the present. Cities are not rebuilt from scratch in every period. Buildings last a long time before they are demolished, and sites that were attractive in the past tend to remain desirable for a long time. One of the unique features of the Olcott’s data set is that it allows us to compare land values from 100 years ago to current land values and land uses.
Figure 4 shows the average date of construction for the 1/8- x 1/8-mile squares. The recent recentralization of Chicago is evident in the donut shape of building ages around the CBD. The newest buildings are close to the CBD, while the oldest buildings are in the next ring. Buildings in the most distant region were most likely built between 1940 and 1970.
Figure 5 summarizes this relationship by comparing the mean construction date to distance from the CBD. The oldest buildings are in a ring just over 5 miles from the CBD.
A good measure of structural density is the ratio of building area to lot size. Economic theory predicts that structural densities will be high where land values are high. Structures last for a long time. How well do past values predict current structural density? Figure 6 compares the structural density of buildings in the 2003 Cook County assessment rolls to land values in 1913 and 1990. This data set includes the building area of every small (six units or fewer) residential structure in Chicago.
The height of the bars indicates the structural densities: Tall bars have relatively high ratios of building areas to lot sizes. The color of the bars indicates land values: Red bars have relatively high and values. Thus, we should expect to see a large number of tall red bars and low green bars. In general, the two panels do indicate a positive correlation between structural density and land values. The correlation is particularly evident on the north side and along the lakefront. The correlation with 1990 is less clear on the south and west sides. Several elevations in the density surface are not matched by correspondingly high land values. One explanation for these results, which are in line with the reorientation of high-priced areas toward the north side, is that the relatively high densities in these areas are artifacts of a past when those blocks were relatively more valuable and when there were incentives to use the land intensively. The 1913 panel of figure 6 suggests that land values are actually more closely correlated with building densities for 2003 than are the 1990 values. The root of this apparently anomalous result is that building density reflects the economic conditions at the time of construction, and most of the buildings in that part of the city date from long ago. The past continues to exert a major influence on the present.
Conclusion
Olcott’s data provide a clear picture of the changes in Chicago’s spatial structure during most of the 20th century. Never a truly monocentric city, Chicago began the century with very high land values in the CBD, along the lakefront, and along major avenues and boulevards leading out of the downtown area. Values were also high in neighborhood retail areas at the intersections of major streets. By 1939, the north side of Chicago had already begun to display its economic dominance. The city then suffered an extended period of decline, with the CBD holding the only major cluster of high land values in the 1960s. Since then, the city has undergone a remarkable resurgence. High land values now extend over nearly the entire north side, and land values have also rebounded in parts of the south side. Our analysis also shows the strong role that history continues to play in the current spatial structure of the city. A result of this persistence is that land values from a century ago are better than current land values at predicting the density of the current housing stock.
Acknowledgments
The authors thank the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy for generous funding and support, and are grateful to the Centre for Metropolitan Studies at the TU-Berlin for hosting a team of researchers during the project work. Kristoffer Moeller and Sevrin Weights are acknowledged for their great contribution to designing and coordinating the compilation of the data set. Philip Boos, Aline Delatte, Nuria-Maria Hoyer Sepulvedra, Devika Kakkar, Rene Kreichauf, Maike Rackwitz, Lea Siebert, Stefan Tornack, and Tzvetelina Tzvetkova provided excellent research assistance.
About the Authors
Gabriel M. Ahlfeldt is associate professor at the London School of Economics and Political Sciences (LSE) in the Department of Geography and Environment and Spatial Economics Research Centre (SERC).
Daniel P. McMillen is professor in the department of economics at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.
Resources
Ahlfeldt, Gabriel M., Kristoffer Moeller, Sevrin Waights, and Nicolai Wendland. 2011. “One Hundred Years of Land Value: Data Documentation.” Centre for Metropolitan Studies, TU Berlin.
Ahlfeldt, Gabriel M., and Nicolai Wendland. 2011. “Fifty Years of Urban Accessibility: The Impact of the Urban Railway Network on the Land Gradient in Berlin 1890–1936.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 41: 77–88.
Atack, J., and R. A. Margo. 1998. “Location, Location, Location! The Price Gradient for Vacant Urban Land: New York, 1835 to 1900.” Journal of Real Estate Finance & Economics 16(2) 151–172.
Colwell, Peter F., and Henry J. Munneke. 1997. “The Structure of Urban Land Prices.” Journal of Urban Economics 41: 321–336.
Cunningham, Christopher R. 2006. “House Price Uncertainty, Timing of Development, and Vacant Land Prices: Evidence for Real Options in Seattle.” Journal of Urban Economics 59: 1–31.
Dye, Richard F., and Daniel P. McMillen. 2007. “Teardowns and Land Values in the Chicago Metropolitan Area.” Journal of Urban Economics 61: 45–64.
Hoyt, Homer. 1933. One Hundred Years of Land Values in Chicago. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
McMillen, Daniel P. 2006. “Teardowns: Costs, Benefits, and Public Policy.” Land Lines, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy 18(3): 2–7.
The study of property taxation in Europe offers special challenges because each country has a different definition of land and property, and a different approach to local property taxation. The term property often includes both land and buildings, but may also include plants and machinery as well as certain possessions, such as automobiles. In Denmark, for example, separate taxes may be levied on the land and property elements of a single holding.
Among the 41 counties in our study, we identified 61 different forms of local taxation. Most are based on annual value, usually assessed on a capital or rental basis, and are payable annually. While most countries tax the sale of property at the state level, the Czech Republic, Italy, Portugal, Slovakia and Spain levy such taxes locally. Yet, amid such diversity, a basic central pattern emerges. Each county, except Malta, operates some form of annual property tax on the use or occupation of land and/or property, usually levied at the local level, and the revenues contribute to the provision of local services.
Tax Reform and the European Union
Over the last 10 years France, Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, Belgium, the United Kingdom and the Republic of Ireland have either completed or are in the process of completing substantial reforms to their taxation systems. Other countries have undertaken more minor reforms. Even some emerging democracies are reviewing and reforming their relatively new taxation systems in light of changes elsewhere. No individual tax exists in isolation, and all are affected by larger fiscal, economic and political developments. The reform of one tax will often have consequential effects on others, and property taxation in all its forms is no exception.
One impetus to tax reform in Europe is the European Union (EU). Fifteen of the countries in our study are members, and many other countries are in various stages of being considered for membership. Many countries are taking this opportunity to reform and improve their tax administration systems and to make their taxation rates competitive with those of other member states. Tax harmonization is not one of the declared aims of the EU, although it may be a natural consequence of many EU polices.
The main incentive for tax reform in Europe is coming from the states themselves. In one of the first signs of the problems caused by traditional national taxation systems, the Ministry of Finance in the Netherlands noted in the early 1990s that not only were businesses locating in the most tax-favorable areas but they also were buying goods and services from other countries where tax rates and other costs were lower. The close proximity of the Netherlands to Germany, France, Belgium and Luxembourg, as well as the good transport links between the countries, exacerbated the situation.
The introduction of the Single European Market has opened internal markets to foreign competition with the removal of trade barriers and the abolition of customs duties between member states. Business competitiveness now depends primarily on efficiency and the amount of taxation imposed by the national government, rather than on state aid and trade policies.
Approaches to Local Taxation
The Taxpayer
The majority of property taxes are payable by the owner. Of the 51 taxes we studied, 29 identified the owner as the taxpayer and 12 are paid by the occupier; the remaining 10 are sales-based taxes. The occupier figure was distorted because the United Kingdom accounted for 50 percent of this figure, due to differences in the implementation of its local taxes. In the Netherlands both parties can be taxed at different amounts. For sales-related taxes the results were less clear, with the taxpayer being the seller in half the cases and the purchaser in the other half.
Sources of Valuation Information
Many countries have some form of computerized cadastral system to record property-related information, and as part of the assessment process different levels of government usually exchange information. The nature and implementation of such systems vary considerably, from a series of different registers administered at various levels of government to a single register administered nationally.
The rights of the taxpayer to centrally held information also differ among countries. Some provide no rights to any information, while others provide notice whenever a new valuation or alteration is made. In some cases, valuation and comparable evidence may be made available at the request of the taxpayer.
Bases of Valuation
Three alternative approaches for the valuation bases are used most frequently. The Capital Value Approach is normally based on the open market value of the property at a specified baseline date, which may be a current date such as the start of the tax year. Sweden designates a date two years before the tax year. This approach has the advantage of giving valuation authorities more time to consider all the evidence available before arriving at their final valuations. The open market value is usually defined on the basis of a property’s best and/or highest value.
The Rental Value Approach is based on the open market rental value at a specified date. England, Wales, Scotland and the Republic of Ireland specify a baseline date some time before the new values come into effect, as in Sweden. The open market rental value may be restricted by assumptions as to changes of use and alterations. The rationale is that the tax is levied on the occupier and the amount of tax is based on the current use of the property, not its potential value.
Properties not normally bought and sold in the market require alternative approaches to valuation. For example, the use of a revenue (or accounts) approach has been adopted in England and Wales for many types of leisure-related property, and its use is expected to increase. The cost approach, related to the cost of construction, also is widely accepted in England and Wales and in other European countries.
The Overall or Unit Approach relates to a property’s size. The tax is levied at a prescribed rate per square meters or per unit, which may vary depending on the predominant use of the property. These rates may be loosely based on rental or capital values, but are more often an arbitrary rate fixed by the appropriate taxation authority. In 1997 the Netherlands moved away from such a system in favor of a market-related capital value approach. Many new democracies have adopted the unit approach due to a lack of property information, a limited and restricted property market, and insufficient resources to enable the development of alternative systems. It is anticipated that many of these countries will move to a value-based system when resources and circumstances permit.
A number of other approaches are used under special circumstances. One is the capital value banding approach adopted for the valuation of residential property for the Council Tax in England, Wales and Scotland. In this approach property is ascribed to various value bands rather than valuing each individual property precisely. Another example is the local business tax, which includes the value of the property plus in the case of France a percentage of salaries and in the case of Spain and Switzerland the business profits.
Revaluation of the Tax Base
One of the key factors in examining European property tax systems is whether the valuations on which the tax is charged are up-to-date. Our research identified a very mixed picture: some countries have not revalued their tax bases for many years and others undertake revaluations regularly, every four or five years (see Table 1). Many countries have either no provision for regular revaluations or have postponed revaluations so often that their tax base bears little resemblance to current market values.
Indexation
Many countries have attempted to overcome the problems associated with infrequent revaluations by some form of indexation. Those countries performing annual revaluations may implement them through actual annual revaluations, indexation of an earlier revaluation or self-assessment declarations by the taxpayer. While annual indexation between regular revaluations every few years may ensure a relatively accurate tax base, its use becomes more questionable when the base has not been updated for 10 or 20 years. The position is made far worse in countries where the property market is changing rapidly, especially in major cities and towns. Any adopted index needs to be closely related to the property market in that location and to the specific property type. In most cases, however, the index is a single figure applied across the entire country and for all types of property.
Exemptions and Reliefs
Exemptions can be considered from two viewpoints: the nature of the property or the nature of the taxpayer. In addition, some countries have introduced arrangements that place a ceiling on the amount of tax payable. Some common features relating to the types of properties for which some form of relief may be granted are:
Relief to taxpayers takes many forms and can include:
Calculating the Amount of Tax
The simplest systems for calculating tax payments adopt a given tax per square meter occupied. Once the area of the property is agreed, it is a relatively simple matter to apply a given tax rate to that area. In some countries, the assessed value must be multiplied by an index or co-efficient and then by a locally determined rate that can vary depending on the size of the authority levying the charge. In France, the situation is even worse for the business tax, where a series of limitations have to be calculated to ascertain whether a ceiling or cap applies to the taxable amount.
Appeal Systems
Most countries have a system by which the taxpayer may challenge the tax assessment or valuation, although that action generally does not postpone the payment of the tax. In some cases the first step is an informal approach to the authority, which may be able to resolve the dispute without the need for more formal action. Where a formal approach is adopted, the appeal may be dealt with as part of the general tax appeal process through the normal tax tribunals and courts, or it may be handled outside the normal tax system, often in courts and tribunals established for the purpose.
Tax Collection and Payment
In many countries taxes are collected by the national tax authority, often as part of the income tax process. This method has the advantage of being linked with national exemptions and benefits; the resulting tax is usually payable over the whole tax year. Under the second common method, the tax is paid directly to the relevant taxing authority, sometimes in installments.
Conclusion
European countries are constantly reviewing their tax systems and adopting the best features of other systems. This presents special challenges to a survey such as ours, but also enhances its potential impact by allowing comparative analysis to influence new legislation. One very important conclusion at this early stage of the research project is the importance of keeping the tax base up-to-date. This not only simplifies the entire valuation and collection process but also ensures a tax base that is more acceptable and understandable to taxpayers. During this year we propose to widen our research and complete data collection on other European countries. In addition, we will attempt to compare the amounts of revenue raised by each type of taxation and analyze them within the context of each country’s local government and finance system.
Peter K. Brown is professor of property taxation at Liverpool John Moores University, a frequent author and a regular speaker on valuation, rating and taxation matters. Moira Hepworth is head of research at the Institute of Revenues, Rating and Valuation (IRRV), based in London. The authors are joint recipients of a David C. Lincoln Fellowship in Land Value Taxation. This article is based on their first year of research and their recent working paper.
Related Publication
Peter K. Brown and Moira Hepworth. 2000. “A Study of European Land Tax Systems.” Lincoln Institute Working Paper. 156 pages.
Governments have often intervened in land markets in Asian cities, but with limited effects. In recent decades, economic globalization and political democratization have created even stronger demands for more efficient and equitable land use policies. Rapid economic growth in cities with scarce land resources has generated a wave of new thinking on land values and land markets among scholars and policymakers.
The GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) negotiations are stimulating new production structures in much of Asia, which consequently shift demand from agriculture into manufacturing and other urban land uses. At the same time, local governments are struggling with more financial autonomy and are becoming dependent on revenues from increased land values to subsidize the costs of development.
Three countries illustrate emerging land and tax policy issues raised by these complex interactions of international and local economies.
In Taiwan, land values for urban and agriculture uses are extremely divergent. The immediate issues are: 1) how to better use the 40,000 hectares of agricultural land that are no longer needed for production as a result of the GATT agreements; and 2) how to distribute the development benefits created by this conversion of agricultural land.
In Korea, the challenge concerns the legality of taxation to capture excessive increases in land value and gains from land speculation. Faced with builders’ pressure to develop greenbelts and open spaces in metropolitan areas and with local politicians’ concerns over fiscal autonomy, the central government is preparing a major tax reform to capture these increments in land value.
In Japan, land values have changed dramatically over the past ten years, but the reasons for these fluctuations are not always clear. Land speculation, unpredictable market forces and government regulation all play a part. Analysis of failed attempts to control land prices will be valuable in developing future policies.
Land Value and Speculation
The perception of land value in Taiwan, Korea, and Japan may not be significantly different from that in other capitalist countries. The problem is in the speculative value, also known as “unearned income” or the “unearned increment” in land value. This value can be so high that it distorts all the legal, administrative, political and social measures designed to manage the use of land. In Japan, for example, land value in major cities tripled from 1983 to 1989. In Korea, land value increased 13 times between 1975 and 1990, while the national income increased only 5 times in the same period. In Taiwan, the value of farm land increased 155 percent from 1986 to 1990, compared to the GDP’s 36 percent growth during the same period.
Policies intended to control land values during periods of high speculation are unlikely to succeed. During the boom times of the 1980s in all three Asian countries, special interest groups and politicians dependent on economic growth failed to anticipate any negative downturn effects. Land policies became disorganized, and conflicts arose among different government departments. For example, some local governments subsidized farmland owners who had already sold their land for conversion to urban uses and had benefited financially from this speculation. Financial institutions provided loans to corporations which depended on land speculation for their corporate earnings. The results were devastating: farmers who wished to farm could not afford to buy farm land; manufacturers could no longer compete when 60 percent of their investments were spent on land costs; and average citizens had an even more difficult time owning a house.
Reevaluating Land and Tax Policy
As land values have dropped in recent years, there is a new opportunity to revise land policies. Special interest groups and land value speculators have softened their opposition to government intervention on land markets. The GATT and WTO (World Trade Organization) negotiations are requiring countries to better coordinate their land policies and general economic policies in the interests of industrial readjustment. Future policies in Taiwan, Korea, and Japan will likely incorporate the following measures:
New regulations will be designed to convert some farmland and environmentally less-sensitive land for housing and mixed-use urban development. The goals are to continue sustainable development and to assist the conversion of the agricultural sector.
Tax reform and exaction-like laws will be introduced to capture the “unearned income” from land speculation. A capital gains tax, land value tax and land value increment tax will be the hallmarks of tax reform. Local government will be given more autonomy to require private developers to share benefits with the community.
Land use planning systems will be coordinated at all levels of government to manage growth. New land use controls will be designed to cope with new economic activities derived from the economic readjustments.
To help advance these land and tax policy reforms, the Lincoln Institute research staff is working with colleagues in each country. The Council of Agriculture in Taiwan, Republic of China, and the Institute are conducting a three-year joint study (1994-97) on land value capture and benefit distribution mechanisms. A team of researchers from the Lincoln Institute and the Korea Tax Institute is researching tax reform for the Korea Ministry of Finance during the 1995-1996 academic year. Both American and Japanese scholars are examining land values in Japan from a macroeconomic perspective.
Alven Lam in a Lincoln Institute fellow whose current research focuses on land value capture and property rights in Asia.
Additional information in the printed newletter.
Chart: Indices of Korea Land Values and Major Economic Indicators: 1980, 1985 and 1990. Land prices, housing prices, national income and wholesale prices are charted. Source: Office of National Statistics, Korea Statistical Yearbook, each year, and Kim, Dai-Young, “Choices for Future Land Policy,” in Land Policy Problems in East Asia, 1994.
Large-scale urban redevelopment projects (termed grandes projectos urbanos or GPUs in Spanish) raise many questions about the impacts of subsequent urban development induced by the intervention. GPUs are characterized by an impact in a significant part of the city, often with the use of some new fiscal or regulatory instruments and the involvement of a large network of agents and institutions. These projects are expected to affect land prices, recycle existing or create new infrastructure and facilities, and attract other new buildings.
GPUs as an urban policy instrument have been the object of considerable controversy and debate throughout Latin America. It is often argued that they promote social exclusion and gentrification, have limited effects in stimulating real estate activities, and require large (sometimes hidden) public subsidies that often draw fiscal resources from other urban needs. In spite of their increasing popularity in Latin America, there is little empirical evidence to support these criticisms.
This article presents the case of a GPU introduced in São Paulo, Brazil, in 1996 as an “urban operation” to redevelop a middle-income area of mostly single-family homes that was to be traversed by the extension of the Faria Lima Avenue. The project is known as the Faria Lima Urban Operation Consortium (OUCFL). We examine economic principles that affect the fiscal performance of the project and its opportunity for value capture, evaluate changes in residential density, and analyze changes in income distribution and ownership structure. Finally, we offer some policy suggestions on how and when to use this kind of instrument based on these assessments.
What is an Urban Operation?
An urban operation is a legal instrument that seeks to provide local governments with the power to undertake interventions related to urbanistic and city planning improvements in association with the private sector. It identifies a particular area within the city that has the potential to attract private real estate investments to benefit the city as a whole. The proper city planning indexes (i.e., zoning and other regulations on construction coefficients, rates of occupation, and land uses) are redefined in accordance with a master plan, and investments are made in new or recycled infrastructure.
An urban operation allows the municipality to capture (through negotiated or mandatory means) the land value increments associated with the subsequent land use changes. In contrast to other value capture instruments, these funds are earmarked or internalized within the perimeter of the project to be shared between government and the private sector for both investments in urban infrastructure and subsidies to private real estate investments to support the project itself.
Each urban operation in Brazil is proposed by the executive and approved by the legislative branch of the jurisdiction. In the case of São Paulo, this authority was created in the Lei Organica Municipal (Constitution of the City) in 1990, which was later inserted in the new Brazilian urban development law (Statute of the City of 2001). The first proposed projects were the Operation Anhangabaú (subsequently expanded as a part of the Downtown Operation and renamed Center Operation) and Água Branca, followed by the Água Espraiada and Faria Lima operations. After the approval of the city’s new Master Plan in 2001, nine other urban operations were generated. These thirteen projects are expected to affect 30 to 40 percent of the buildable area of the City of São Paulo.
Financing Faria Lima
The Faria Lima urban operation (OUCFL) was proposed and approved in 1995 with the aim of obtaining private resources to fund the public investments necessary to purchase land and install infrastructure in order to extend Faria Lima Avenue. These costs were deemed at the time to be approximately US$150 million, two-thirds for land acquisitions and one-third for the avenue itself. The project was heavily contested by many stakeholders on grounds ranging from the source of the funds (i.e., advanced out of the local budget through new debt) to neighborhood concerns (one of which managed to keep the floor-area-ratios [FARs] unchanged and legally excluded from the OUCFL zoning) and technical design issues.
Technical studies carried out at the time indicated that it would be possible to take advantage of an additional potential 2,250,000 square meters beyond what was already permitted by the city’s zoning legislation, and the FARs were changed accordingly. These additional building rights were granted against a payment of a minimum of 50 percent of their market value using the existing “Solo-Criado” (Selling of Building Rights) instrument. OUCFL aroused great interest on the part of real estate entrepreneurs. This instrument nevertheless was also questioned for its lack of transparency, its project by project approach, and the arbitrariness in the way relevant prices were established and then used to calculate the value of the additional building rights.
By August 2003 a total of 939,592 square meters, or nearly 42 percent of the available total of these 2,250,000 square meters, had already been licensed. More than 115 real estate projects were approved, including nearly 40 percent commercial buildings and 60 percent high-quality residential buildings. Nevertheless, the resources (approximately US$280 million) obtained from these approved projects had not fully compensated for the expenditures (US$350 million, including principal plus interest) associated with the expansion of the avenue, considering the high interest rates prevailing in Brazil for the nearly eight years since the realization of expenditures. Thus, about 80 percent of the cost (albeit more than anticipated) has been recovered through the Selling of Building Rights process. Since July 2004 the compensation for these advance funds was obtained through an ingenious new value capture mechanism known as CEPAC, an acronym for a Certificate of Additional Potential of Construction. One CEPAC represents one square meter.
The Introduction of CEPACs
Although CEPACs were defined in Brazil’s Statute of the City of 2001, they were not approved by the CVM (Brazilian equivalent to the U.S. Security and Exchange Commission) as freely tradable in the Brazilian Stock Exchange until December 2003. The regulation establishes that the price of each certificate is defined by public auction and that the corresponding square meters of building rights (which also include use changes and occupation rates) expressed in each certificate may be executed at any time. The regulation also states that new batches of certificates can be issued (and sold through auction) only upon confirmation that the resources captured by the previous sale have been effectively earmarked to the project. To ensure this designated use, the revenues are deposited in a special account, not in the municipal treasury. From the perspective of the private investors this designation ensures the acceptability of this value capture instrument at its own valorization. By issuing a lower number of certificates than potential building rights—that is by managing their scarcity—the public sector may benefit from the valorization and thus be able to capture value “ex-ante” (Afonso 2004, 39).
The final approval of CEPACs for OUCFL and all the necessary steps for launching them in the financial market occurred in mid-2004, and the first auction at the end of December 2004 generated nearly R$10 million (about US$4 million), corresponding to the sale of approximately 9,000 CEPACs out of an authorized stock of 650,000 square meters. The OUCFL certificates were sold at a face value of R$1,100 (about US$450) per square meter with no observed premium pricing as a result of the bidding process.
This situation contrasts with that of the Água Espraiada urban operation, which was expected to be fully funded by CEPACs from its start. In its third auction, the certificates were already capturing R$370 per certificate against a face value of R$300 set for this operation. A more recent auction in Água Espraiada sold 56,000 CEPACs and captured R$21 million ($US9.5 million), reflecting a certificate price of R$371. This pricing contrast reflects the different original face values in the two projects. In the case of OUCFL developers bought (and stocked) building rights in advance, to benefit from the more flexible rules prior to the CVM approvals. The certificate price in Faria Lima started at more than R$1,100 because it is a more valued area. In Água Espraiada developers were willing to pay more than the original face value because the certificates were less expensive and thus in greater demand.
Land Price Implications
The prices of vacant land and developed areas experienced a considerable increase in some blocks within the perimeter of OUCFL during the 1990s, but decreased in other blocks. Yet, the average square meter price of new real estate development fell throughout the Metropolitan Region of São Paulo (RMSP) in all price bands, when comparing the average price from 1991 to 1996 with those of 1996 to 2000.
After controlling for a number of attributes associated with the changing character of the developments and their location, the price estimations showed an unequivocal relative increase after the operation was launched. The average price per square meter within the OUCFL perimeter increased from R$1.68 thousand in the 1991–1996 period to R$1.92 thousand in the 1996–2001 period, a 14 percent increase, while prices in RMSP decreased from R$1.21 thousand to R$1.06 thousand, a 12 percent decrease in the same period (R$1.95/US$1.00 in December 2000). Thus, the price per square meter in OUCFL was higher than that of RMSP by around 26 percent. The price per square meter in OUCFL was 38 percent higher than the average price in the RMSP in 1991–1996, and it increased to 81 percent higher in 1996–2001.
Was this increase captured by the municipality as anticipated? Considering that the cost of construction in average is around R$1,000 per square meter, the 2004 auction (the only one so far) captured almost all of the value added at current prices. The previous pre-CEPAC system captured about 50 percent or more, depending on the capacity and success of municipal negotiators, and the correctness of the reference price. CEPAC now changes this percentage and the face value of the instrument may capture all the value increment or even more, depending on the relation of this face value to market prices, and on the results of future auctions. Comparing a redevelopment project financed totally by construction bonds (like CEPACs) and one financed totally with general property taxes, there is no doubt that the former is less regressive than the latter. Even with a progressive property tax, with rates increasing according to values, part of the costs would be paid by poorer households.
This evidence that about 80 percent of the total cost of the project has already been recovered, combined with the auctioning of the remaining building rights through CEPACs and the impact of the property appreciation on the current property tax revenues, indicates that the project should not only pay its own way but actually generate a fiscal surplus for the city as a whole over the next five or seven years.
In effect, the changes caused by substituting older single-family houses with new residential and commercial buildings resulted in a substantial change in property tax collection in the OUCFL area. Many lots and even entire blocks had been occupied by single- and two-story houses constructed since the 1950s. Many of these structures were eligible for a discount coefficient for obsolescence of up to 30 percent of the property tax. They were replaced with new, taller and higher-quality buildings for which the discount was null. Our estimates indicate that the differences in property tax collection by square meters constructed may have increased by at least 2.7 times and up to 4.4 times. That is, the average property tax per square meter increased to a minimum of R$588.50 up to R$802.50 from R$220.95 if the house was 25 years old, or from R$179.70 if the house was 30 years old.
Social Implications
The OUCFL case offers a unique opportunity to quantify changes in resident characteristics before and after the intervention, since data at the census track level is available for 1991 and 2000, and the intervention began in 1996. Our analysis of gentrification and displacement of poorer residents mainly confirms the findings of Ramalho and Meyer (2004) that the average income has increased relatively in most of the blocks inside the OUCFL perimeter. By Brazilian standards, the upper-middle class was displaced from the region by the richest 5 percent of households in the metropolitan area. The census data also showed that residential density fell between 1991 and 2000, from 27 to 22 residences per hectare, although these figures may be distorted because they reflect the ratio of total residences in the entire area, not an average of the ratios per plot where land use was converted.
The data from 1991 indicated that the population was already leaving the OUCFL area before the approval of the urban operation, but this exodus intensified after 1996, generating vacant plots in the process of site-assembly to accommodate the new high-rise developments. At the same time, building density increased. The average number of floors per new building in the area increased from 12.6 in the 1985–1995 period to 16.7 in the 1996–2001 period. The number of housing units per building increased from 37.1 to 79.6 over the same periods.
This apparent contradiction between decreased residential density and increased numbers of housing units is explained in part by the construction of commercial buildings that replaced many single-family residencies on small and average-sized lots. OUCFL induced considerable real estate concentration as the new commercial and residential buildings replaced the houses and required greater land areas for high-class architectural projects. The 115 projects approved between 1995 and August 2003 that requested increases in the utilization coefficients required a total of 657 lots, or an average of 5.7 lots per project.
The combination of the increase in income level and the reduction in household density indicates that the gentrification process advanced in and around the OUCFL region during the 1990s. Nevertheless, this is not a classic case of gentrification, where poor families are driven out of an area due to various socioeconomic pressures. In this case mostly upper-middle classes were displaced. Except for the small nucleus of remaining favelados (Favela Coliseu), the region was already occupied by people belonging to the richest segments of society.
Some Policy Observations
This article contributes to the debate about the social management of land valuation by furnishing real data assessments and economic elements. These elements have been missing from most analysis, and we believe that this gap in the literature has contributed to an incomplete interpretation of the implications of an urban operation and to mistaken public policy recommendations.
Our conclusion is that the CEPAC funding mechanism itself does not increase the regressive characteristic of urban operations, since without those building rights bonds all the investment in redevelopment would be financed by general taxes. If the OUCFL project were inadequate in terms of income distribution, it would have been even worse without the value capture mechanism. Instead, CEPAC and the value capture mechanism used previously offered two desirable characteristics of any public investment: charging the new landowners is at least neutral in terms of income distribution; and the primary beneficiaries end up paying for the project.
Furthermore, the urban operation mechanism offers incentives for redevelopment. Given that most projects increase land prices and drive out the poor from the region, it would be better to invest the entire municipal budget in small-scale projects. This is the opposite of what happened with the redevelopment of the adjacent high-end Berrini area where developers decided how to concentrate their investment, resulting in even more income concentration than in the OUCFL area. Because of inaction by policy makers in that case, the municipality did not capture any value from Berrini, yet paid the entire cost of infrastructure.
The use of building rights bonds may diminish the regressive aspect of land development, but to make a project truly progressive requires attention on the expense side, by funding all the investment through instruments like CEPACs. The main limitation on distributing benefits to the poor is that the law establishes that all funds collected through value capture (CEPACs or other instruments) must be invested within the perimeter of the intervention. One way to make these interventions more progressive is to invest in activities that will furnish spillovers to the poor, such as public transit, education, and health. Moreover the relevant legislation allows the administration to select an area inside the perimeter of an urban operation and declare it a zone of special social interest (ZEIS) where lots can be used only for low-income social housing.
Another alternative is to establish social housing areas within the perimeter of the urban operation. By subsidizing low-income housing with money from developers and new landowners, there would be no distortion in prices outside of the housing industry. The subsidy results from segmenting the market and transferring the extra rent to poor households. This is real social management of land valuation.
Ciro Biderman is affiliated with the Center for Studies of Politics and Economics of the Public Sector (Cepesp) at the Economic and Business School at the Getúlio Vargas Foundation in São Paulo, Brazil. He is a visiting fellow in international development and regional planning in the Department of Urban Studies and Planning at Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge.
Paulo Sandroni is an economist and professor at the Economic and Business School at the Getúlio Vargas Foundation.
Martim O. Smolka is senior fellow and director of the Lincoln Institute’s Program on Latin America and the Caribbean.
Photograph Credit: wsfurlan via iStock / Getty Images Plus.
References
(These publications are available only in Portuguese.)
Afonso, Luis Carlos Fernandes. 2004. Financiamento eh desafio para governantes (Financing is a challenge to government). Teoria ane Debate No. 58, Maio-Junho: 36–39.
Ramalho, T., e R.M.P. Meyer. 2004. O impacto da Operação Urbana Faria Lima no uso residencial: Dinâmicas de transformação (The impact of the Faria Lima Urban Operation on residential use: Transformation dynamics). Mimeo. São Paulo: Lume/FAUUSP.
Biderman, Ciro, e Paulo Sandroni. 2005. Avaliação do impacto das grandes intervenções urbanas nos precos dos imoveis do entorno: O caso da Operação Urbana Consorciada Faria Lima (Evaluation of property price impacts near large-scale urban interventions: The case of Faria Lima Urban Operation Consortium). Lincoln Institute of Land Policy Research Report (April).
How will local government finances be affected by the large and increasing burden to pay for previously obligated pension costs? How, in particular, will these pension legacy costs change residents’ perceptions of the local property tax and their willingness to pay? As a first step in a larger Lincoln Institute of Land Policy research agenda on these questions, we ask: What is known–and just as importantly, what is not known–about the magnitude of unfunded local government pension liabilities in the United States? (see Gordon, Rose, and Fischer 2012)
It is a first principle of public finance that current services should be paid with current revenues and that debt finance should be reserved for capital projects that provide services to future taxpayers. This principle is violated when pension liabilities associated with current labor services are not funded by current purchases of financial assets and instead have to be paid for by future taxpayers.
Alas, principles of prudence in public finance are not always observed, and local governments in the United States have accumulated substantial unfunded pension liabilities in recent years. This situation breaks an important link in the relationship between taxpayers and the services they receive–the rough correspondence between the overall value of public services and the resources taken from the private sector. There is considerable debate about the strength of this correspondence and how price-like the relationship is between value paid and value received for individual taxpayers, but there can be little question that using current revenues to pay for past services weakens the link.
Growing Public Awareness
State and local government employee pensions are in the headlines almost daily (box 1). Only a few years ago, they were the nearly exclusive province of a few elected officials, appointed boards, investment advisors, actuaries, and credit rating agencies. What changed? The most immediate answer is the Great Recession, which sapped not only state tax revenue but also the value of pension plan assets. In particular, state and local pension fund equity holdings lost nearly half of their value, dropping from a peak of $2.3 trillion in September 2007 to a low of $1.2 trillion in March 2009 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2012).
———–
Box 1: Where Are Local Pensions in Trouble?
To understand where local pensions were experiencing particular difficulties, Gordon, Rose, and Fischer (2012) used media monitoring software to conduct a search of all U.S. domestic news outlets for the first three months of 2012. To satisfy the query, articles had to include the word “pension” in conjunction with terms that identify local governments (e.g., municipality, city, or county) and descriptions of funding problems (e.g., liability, deficit, underfunded, cut, default, reform, or problem). The search yielded over 2,000 separate articles from places all over the country.
Their analysis suggests several types of places are experiencing pension troubles. One group consists of jurisdictions that have been losing people and jobs over time. A prominent example is Detroit, Michigan, which has twice as many retirees as active workers. Also in this category is Prichard, Alabama, which has lost more than 45 percent of its population since 1970 and by 2010 had fewer than 23,000 residents. It simply stopped sending pension checks to its former employees in September 2009 and declared bankruptcy one month later. For such communities, pension problems may also be a symptom of larger fiscal distress or political dysfunction.
Another group of jurisdictions rode the housing boom and bust. Examples include fast-growing California cities like Stockton, which just entered bankruptcy proceedings this year, the largest city ever to do so. More puzzling are relatively affluent places, such as New York’s Suffolk or Nassau Counties, which appear unable to make tough spending cuts or raise taxes because of political gridlock. Instead, many of these jurisdictions have turned to borrowing to meet their pension obligations.
Only two recent municipal bankruptcies (Vallejo, California, and Central Falls, Rhode Island) stemmed from public pensions and employee compensation pressures together with falling revenues. Other places such as Harrisburg, Pennsylvania, and Jefferson County, Alabama, are struggling with poor investment decisions. Also, major cities such as Atlanta, San Francisco, and New York have taken steps to limit pension growth, often with cooperation from local public employee unions. Central Falls managed to extract concessions from active police officers and fire fighters as well as current retirees, but even this was insufficient to stop the slide toward bankruptcy.
Although stock markets have largely recovered and state and local plan equity holdings have climbed back over $2 trillion, public pensions remain under scrutiny. Credit rating agencies increasingly are taking unfunded pension liabilities into account when developing their assessments of state and local government borrower risk. In addition, analysts are growing more vocal in their criticisms of methods commonly used to evaluate pension funding levels.
The federal government is also paying attention. Alarmed by the prospect of defaults, Congress held a series of hearings into state and local government finances in early 2011. More recently, the Republican staff of the Joint Economic Committee (JEC) has issued reports raising the specter of a Eurozone-like crisis due to unfunded state pension liabilities (JEC 2011; JEC 2012).
In light of these criticisms and concerns about growing pension costs, 43 states enacted significant reforms to their pension systems between 2009 and 2011 (Snell 2012). The most common changes were: increased employee contribution requirements (30 states); raised age and service for eligibility (32); adjusted formulas for calculating benefits (17); and reduced cost of living increases (21). In some states the changes applied to new employees only, but in others they affected active workers and current retirees. The latter actions have proven especially controversial, prompting lawsuits in Colorado, Minnesota, New Jersey, and South Dakota.
Most of the heightened attention to government employee pensions has concentrated on state government plans, while local public employee pensions remain relatively unexplored. Although local plans represent a modest share of total public pension membership (10 percent) and assets (18 percent), their failures could be devastating. Mobile residents and businesses could flee communities that levy higher taxes to rebuild pension assets rather than to provide basic services. A shrinking tax base would leave the fund even worse off and potentially less able to pay promised benefits. The result could be more cities like Prichard, Alabama.
Looking at State and Local Pension Plans Together
State and local pensions are an important part of the nation’s retirement system. Figure 1 shows the distribution of the total of $15.3 trillion in retirement assets at the end of 2011 by type of plan. State and local public employee retirement funds held a combined $2.8 trillion in assets, or almost one-fifth of the total.
Every state has at least one public employee pension plan and some have many. There are more than 220 state plans—some of which are state-administered plans that cover local government workers—and almost 3,200 local government plans (table 1). Together these plans cover 14.7 million current workers, 8.2 million current beneficiaries, and 4.8 million people eligible for future benefits but not yet receiving them.
State and local pensions are all the more important because 27.5 percent of government employees do not participate in Social Security (Nuschler, Shelton, and Topoleski 2011). These uncovered public employees are highly concentrated in a handful of states. Figure 2 ranks the 16 states with the highest concentrations of government workers not covered by Social Security. Almost all state and local government employees in Ohio and Massachusetts and more than half in Nevada, Louisiana, Colorado, California, and Texas are not covered.
Another key feature of state and local pensions is that they are mostly defined benefit (DB) plans. Benefits are calculated by a formula, typically something like:
(Average salary in final 3 years) x
(Years of service) x
(2% for each year of service) =
Benefits
Most state and local government pensions also include a cost of living adjustment. A minority of public sector workers are enrolled in defined contribution (DC) plans where a specified amount is put in a retirement fund for each year of work. Compared to DC plans, DB pensions protect employees from investment, inflation, and longevity risks. As of 2009, nearly 80 percent of state and local workers were enrolled in DB plans and just over 20 percent were in DC plans. Private sector workers had the opposite mix: 20 percent in DB plans and 80 percent in DC plans (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics 2011).
DB plans used to be more prevalent in the private sector but have been disappearing partly because the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA) imposed minimum funding standards, required insurance contributions, and other administrative burdens on them.
The weaker funding and reporting requirements that apply to public pensions allow governments to shift labor costs into the future. This is an implicit form of borrowing that can evade balanced budget rules and avoid the voter approval usually required for issuing bonds.
Funding and Reporting Requirements for State and Local Pensions
For most of their history, state and local pensions were financed out of general revenues on a pay-as-you-go basis. The current practice of prefunding state and local pension plans began in the 1970s and 1980s. While public sector plans were not covered by ERISA, the act did mandate a report on their practices. The 1978 report found a “high degree of pension cost blindness . . . due to the lack of actuarial valuations, the use of unrealistic actuarial assumptions, and the general absence of actuarial standards” (Munnell et al. 2008, 2).
This wake-up call led to voluntary increases in funding levels by many plans and increased attention to actuarial and accounting standards. The Government Accounting Standards Board (GASB) was formed in 1984, issued its first rules for pension plans in 1986, and extensively revised its actuarial valuation standards in 1994. Compliance with these rules is voluntary, but is rewarded by credit rating agencies, auditors, and other data consumers. Unlike ERISA rules that require specific valuation methods for all private plans, GASB sets out criteria that allow some latitude as to which specific methods are used by public plans. As a consequence there are serious transparency and comparability concerns with the self-reported data on state and local pension plan liabilities.
Employer Contribution
The calculation of a plan’s Actuarial Accrued Liability (AAL) requires the following information: ages and salary histories of members; assumptions for salary growth, retirement ages, asset earnings, and inflation; longevity probability tables; and a discount rate to translate estimated future values into present values. Unfunded Actuarial Accrued Liability (UAA L) equals AAL minus plan assets.
The “Normal Cost” of a pension plan is the increase in AAL due to the current year of service by existing employees. ERISA requires that normal cost be covered by employee and employer contributions. GASB specifies an “Annual Required Contribution” (ARC) of normal cost plus a 30-year amortization of UAA L. The problem is that, contrary to its name, payment of ARC is not strictly required in most jurisdictions.
Choice of Discount Rate
The issue that has received the most recent attention is the choice of discount rate. Current GASB rules allow discounting future liabilities based on projected investment returns, which averaged 8 percent per year prior to the recession. But most economists and financial theorists would agree with Brown and Wilcox (2009, 538) that “the discount rate used to value future pension liabilities should reflect the riskiness of the liabilities,” not the assets. Constitutional and other legal guarantees make government pensions of low risk, while historical investment returns include a risk premium.
State and local governments cannot avoid longterm risks such as a protracted productivity slump or a decade-long down market. Therefore, the historical long-term rate of return on an equity-heavy portfolio–before risk adjustment–is too high a discount rate. Higher discount rates can make pensions appear better funded than they truly are. This reduces contribution requirements and imposes unwarranted obligations on future taxpayers if the high rates of return are not achieved. Worse, there is an incentive for plan managers to seek high-risk portfolios in order to get a higher discount rate and lower ARC.
There are strong arguments that the 8 percent discount rate used by many public pension plans is too high, but there is less agreement on just how much lower the appropriate rate should be. Rather than review the arguments, we report one estimate of just how much of an impact a lower rate would have. Munnell et al. (2012) calculate the would-be change in reported liabilities if all plans used a 5 percent rather than an 8 percent discount rate. They estimate that state and local liabilities would increase from $3.6 trillion to $5.4 trillion and aggregate funding ratios (Assets/AAL) would fall from 75 to only 50 percent. This is a huge change, and represents a doubling of unfunded liabilities (UAA L = AAL – Assets).
Recent Changes in GASB Standards
GASB (2012) has released new accounting standards to take effect in 2013 and 2014. The key change requires state and local governments to apply different discount rates to the funded and unfunded portions of liabilities. An earnings-based rate will still be applied to the funded portion, but a lower, riskless rate will be applied to UAA Ls. The impact of this change on reported liabilities depends on how well funded a plan is: no change for fully funded plans; a small change for well funded plans; and large increases in reported liabilities and decreases in funding ratios for poorly funded plans. The new standards also require that the UAA L be shown on the government’s balance sheet, which will increase the visibility of unfunded liabilities to voters.
What Do We Know About Local Pensions?
Despite mounting concerns about the fiscal health of local pension plans, systematic knowledge about them is rare. The best available information comes from the U.S. Census Bureau’s (2012) Annual Survey of State and Local Public Employee Retirement Systems. Detailed data for each government entity is reported every five years. Plan-level data for a sample that includes roughly half of the 3,200 local plans is reported each year and is used to create estimates of totals for each state by type of government. Tables 1 and 2 exemplify the types of information in the survey.
The main virtues of the Census Bureau’s employee retirement survey are its quality and comprehensiveness. A key disadvantage is lack of timeliness, since the most recent local data available is for fiscal year 2010. Another problem is that the Bureau only recently began reporting plan liabilities, and it does so only for state plans. Like other pension data sources, the Census Bureau does not collect information on DC plans or other post-employment benefits (OPEBs).
Nevertheless, the employee retirement survey provides some insights into local pensions. For example, the number of local plans per state varies greatly: 7 states have no local plans; 20 states have fewer than 10; Florida and Illinois have over 300 each; and Pennsylvania has over 1,400. The number of active members per beneficiary is a crude measure of how well employee contributions can fund the plan. Table 1 indicates the national average for local plans is 1.4 workers per retiree, but there is considerable variation across states. This support ratio is less than 1 in 12 states; between 1 and 2 in 31 states; and over 2 in 7 states, with Utah having the highest ratio at 6.8.
Neither of these pieces of information tell us how well funded local pensions are. For this information, we must turn to independent surveys. Most have good coverage of state plans, but they generally survey only a few of the larger local plans: e.g., the National Association of State Retirement Administrators’ (NASRA ) annual survey of member plans. A small number of national studies have focused on local, as opposed to state, pension liabilities. For example, Novy-Marx and Rauh (2011) analyze local pension finances using data from Consolidated Annual Financial Reports (CAFRs) for city and county plans holding more than $1 billion in assets as of 2006.
The Boston College Center for Retirement Research (CRR) maintains a Public Plans Database (PPD) for the largest state and local plans with data from individual plan actuarial reports and local government CAFRs. Using the PPD plus information on some additional local plans, CRR recently issued a report with data for 2010 from a sample of 97 plans in 40 states (Munnell et al. 2011). This is a modest sample relative to the total of 3,200 local plans, but by concentrating on large plans it covers 59 percent of local pension assets and 55 percent of participants.
An important finding is the wide dispersion around the average funding ratio of 77 percent in 2010 (figure 3). Of 95 large plans in the CRR sample with usable information, only 16 had assets covering more than 90 percent of liabilities. At the other tail are 9 plans with below 50 percent funding (Munnell et al. 2011). This study also shows the ARC as a percent of local government payroll. The overall average for 2010 is 22 percent, and again there is wide dispersion (figure 4). Of 91 large plans in the CRR sample with usable information, more than half (49) have ARC below 20 percent of payroll, but 16 have shares in the less manageable 30 to 80 percent range. Five plans have such large pension obligations that if paid in full they would cost more than 100 percent of payroll.
Keep in mind that local governments in most states are not required to pay the full amount of the ARC. We do not have data at the local level, but a state-level study reported wide variation in the percent of ARC actually paid across plans, across years, and across states (State Budget Crisis Task Force 2012). Munnell et al. (2011) calculate pension payments actually made as a share of local budgets and again find considerable variation, with 14 percent of the sample governments devoting more than 12 percent of their budgets to pay for pensions.
Conclusions
Local government pensions are on average significantly underfunded. The key reason is that, absent a legal compulsion to do so, many governments have not set aside enough funds each year to cover the extra pension liabilities incurred in that year, much less to amortize unfunded liabilities from earlier years. In effect, they are borrowing to pay for current labor services and shifting the burden to future taxpayers.
We know much less about the 3,200 locally administered plans that we do about the 220 state plans. The best information on local plans comes from researchers who review the detailed financial reports of the plans and local governments. Of necessity, these studies concentrate on the larger plans. We do know that there is wide variation across plans on key measures: the share of liabilities that are covered by assets; the would-be full contribution to cover both current year pension costs and amortization of unfunded liabilities (ARC) relative to payroll or annual revenues; the share of ARC that is actually paid; and the share of the current budget that goes to pension costs. A significant fraction of local governments are in trouble by one or more of these measures.
Worse, what we know about liabilities comes from municipalities’ self-reported data and their own choice of discount rate. In almost all cases this discount rate is inappropriately high, and the use of a lower discount could more than double unfunded liabilities. The result is a big problem with local pension liabilities that threatens local government finances, but we do not know how big, and we do not know how unequally it is distributed.
About the Authors
Richard F. Dye is a visiting fellow of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. He is also a professor at the Institute of Government and Public Affairs, University of Illinois at Chicago, and professor of economics emeritus at Lake Forest College.
Tracy Gordon is a fellow in Economic Studies at the Brookings Institution, Washington, DC. Her research focuses on state and local public finance, political economy, and urban economics.
References
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2012. Flow of funds accounts of the United States, June 7. http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/data.htm
Brown, Jeffrey R., and David W. Wilcox. 2009. Discounting state and local pension liabilities. American Economic Review 99(2): 538–542.
Gordon, Tracy M., Heather M. Rose, and Ilana Fischer. 2012. The state of local government pensions: A preliminary inquiry. Working Paper. Cambridge MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Governmental Accounting Standards Board (GASB). 2012. GASB Improves Pension Accounting and Reporting Standards. Press Release. June 25. http://www.gasb.org/cs/ContentServer?c=GASBContent_C&pagename=GASB/GASBContent_C/GASBNewsPage&cid=1176160126951
Joint Economic Committee (JEC). 2011. States of bankruptcy, part I: The coming state pensions crisis. Republican Staff Commentary, Washington, DC, December 8.
Joint Economic Committee (JEC). 2012. States of bankruptcy, part II: Eurozone, USA? Republican Staff Commentary, Washington, DC, May 15.
Munnell, Alicia H., Jean-Pierre Aubry, Josh Hurwitz, and Laura Quimby. 2011. An update on locally administered pension plans. Center for Retirement Research at Boston College Policy Brief, July.
Munnell, Alicia H., Jean-Pierre Aubry, Josh Hurwitz, and Laura Quimby. 2012. The funding of state and local pensions: 2011–2015. Center for Retirement Research at Boston College Policy Brief, May.
Munnell, Alicia H., Kelly Haverstick, Steven A. Sass, and Jean-Pierre Aubry. 2008. The miracle of funding by state and local pension plans. Center for Retirement Research at Boston College Policy Brief, April.
Novy-Marx, Robert, and Joshua Rauh. 2011. The crisis in local government pensions in the United States. In Growing old: Paying for retirement and institutional money management after the financial crisis, Robert Litan and Richard Herring, eds., 47–74. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Nuschler, Dawn, Alison M. Shelton, and John J. Topoleski. 2011. Social Security: Mandatory coverage of new state and local government employees. Congressional Research Service, July. http://www.nasra.org/resources/CRS%202011%20Report.pdf
Snell, Ronald K. 2012. State pension reform, 2009–2011. Washington, DC: National Council of State Legislatures, March.
State Budget Crisis Task Force. 2012. Report of the State Budget Crisis Task Force. http://www.statebudgetcrisis.org/wpcms/wp-content/images/Report-of-the-State-Budget-Crisis-Task-Force-Full.pdf
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2011. Employee benefits survey, retirement benefits: access, participation, and take-up rates. March.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2012. 2010 annual survey of state and local public employee retirement systems. http://www.census.gov/govs/retire
Uno de los argumentos principales para justificar la tributación del valor del suelo es que no crea ningún incentivo para alterar el comportamiento con el objeto de evadir el pago del impuesto. En contraste, un impuesto sobre la propiedad convencional, que se grava sobre los edificios, puede frenar la intención de los propietarios de erigir estructuras en su terreno que de otra manera serían deseables. Por ejemplo, los propietarios pueden dejar un sótano sin terminar o no agregar un segundo baño, porque ello aumentaría su obligación tributaria. Por lo tanto, un impuesto sobre la propiedad convencional llevaría a relaciones de capital/suelo excesivamente bajas y un ‘carga excedente’, es decir un costo para los contribuyentes mayor que el mero pago monetario efectuado a las autoridades fiscales. Este artículo informa sobre un estudio reciente de carga excedente al antecesor británico del impuesto moderno sobre la propiedad: el impuesto sobre la ventana, del siglo XVII.
El caso del impuesto sobre la ventana
En 1696, el Rey Guillermo III de Inglaterra, en apremiante necesidad de recursos adicionales, introdujo un impuesto sobre la unidad de vivienda que gravaba la cantidad de ventanas de una morada. El impuesto fue diseñado como un impuesto sobre la propiedad, tal como se deduce del debate en la Cámara de los Comunes en 1850: “El impuesto sobre la ventana, cuando se lo concibió, no tenía intención de tributar una ventana sino una propiedad, ya que se consideraba que una casa era una estimación segura del valor de los bienes de una persona, y se suponía que la cantidad de ventanas era un buen índice del valor de la casa” (HCD, 9 de abril de 1850).
En su forma inicial, el impuesto consistió en una tasa única de 2 chelines por cada casa y un cargo adicional de 4 chelines sobre casas que tenían entre 10 y 20 ventanas, u 8 chelines sobre casas que tenían más de 20 ventanas. La estructura tarifaria se fue enmendando a lo largo de los años; en algunos casos, las tasas crecieron significativamente. En respuesta, los dueños de las moradas intentaron reducir sus facturas de impuestos tapando ventanas o construyendo casas con muy pocas ventanas. En algunas viviendas había pisos enteros sin ventanas, lo que causaba efectos adversos muy graves para la salud. En un caso, la falta de ventilación causó la muerte de 52 personas en el pueblo circundante, según el informe de un médico local que fue llamado a una casa ocupada por familias pobres:
“Para reducir el impuesto sobre la ventana, todas las ventanas de las que todavía podían prescindir los pobres habían sido clausuradas, y por lo tanto se eliminaron todas las fuentes de ventilación. El olor dentro de la casa era sobrecogedor y nauseabundo hasta un extremo insoportable. No había ninguna evidencia de que se hubiera importado la fiebre a esta casa, sino que más bien se propagó de la misma a otras partes del pueblo, y 52 moradores murieron” (Guthrie 1867).
La gente protestó y presentó numerosas peticiones ante el Parlamento. Pero a pesar de sus efectos perniciosos, el impuesto duró más de 150 años, hasta que fue finalmente revocado en 1851.
Para la mayor parte de las familias, el impuesto sobre la ventana representaba una suma sustancial. En Londres, oscilaba entre aproximadamente el 30 por ciento del valor de renta en “casas más pequeñas de la calle Baker” hasta el 40 al 50 por ciento en otras calles, según un debate en la Cámara de los Comunes de 1850 (HCD, 9 de abril de 1850). El impuesto era particularmente oneroso para familias pobres que vivían en conventillos, donde los tasadores tributaban el impuesto a los residentes en forma colectiva. Por lo tanto, si un edificio contenía 2 apartamentos, cada uno de ellos con 6 ventanas, el impuesto se cobraba sobre 12 ventanas. En contraste, en las casas muy grandes de los ricos, el impuesto normalmente no excedía del 5 por ciento del valor de renta.
La tasa de impuestos sufrió varios cambios importantes antes de ser finalmente revocada. En 1784, el Primer Ministro William Pitt aumentó las tasas tributarias para compensar la reducción del impuesto sobre el té. Después, en 1797, la Ley de Triple Tributo de Pitt triplicó la tasa tributaria para ayudar a financiar las guerras napoleónicas. Al día siguiente de esta nueva ley, los ciudadanos cubrieron miles de ventanas y escribieron con tiza en los espacios cubiertos: “Ilumina nuestra oscuridad, ¡te rogamos oh Pitt!” (HCD, 24 de febrero de 1848).
Inglaterra y Escocia estaban sujetas al impuesto sobre la ventana, pero Irlanda estaba exenta debido a su estado de pobreza. Un miembro del Parlamento bromeó: “Al abogar por la extensión del impuesto sobre la ventana a Irlanda, el honorable caballero parece haber olvidado que una ventana inglesa y una ventana irlandesa son cosas muy distintas. En Inglaterra, la ventana es para dejar que entre la luz; pero en Irlanda, la ventana se usa para dejar que se vaya el humo” (HCD, 5 de mayo de 1819).
El impuesto sobre la ventana, dicho sea de paso, era considerado una mejoría con respecto a su antecesor, el impuesto sobre el hogar. En 1662, Carlos II (después de la Restauración) impuso un tributo de 2 chelines sobre cada hogar y estufa en Inglaterra y Gales. El impuesto generó una gran indignación, sobre todo por el carácter entrometido del proceso de tasación. Los “chimeneros”, como llamaban a los tasadores y cobradores de impuestos, tenían que entrar en la casa para contar la cantidad de hogares y estufas. El impuesto sobre la ventana, en contraste, no exigía acceso al interior de la morada; los “mirones de ventanas” podían contar los vanos desde el exterior sin invadir la privacidad del hogar.
El impuesto sobre la ventana, sin embargo, creó algunos problemas administrativos propios, sobre todo con respecto a la definición de ventana con fines tributarios. La ley era vaga y frecuentemente no quedaba claro qué era una ventana para el cobro de impuestos. En 1848, por ejemplo, el profesor Scholefield de Cambridge pagó impuestos por un agujero en la pared de su depósito de carbón (HCD, 24 de febrero de 1848). El mismo año, el Sr. Gregory Gragoe de Westminster pagó impuesto por una trampilla de entrada a su sótano (HCD, 24 de febrero de 1848). Todavía tan tarde como en 1850, los contribuyentes urgían al Secretario del Tesoro que aclarara cuál era la definición de ventana.
Las tallas y sus efectos sobre el comportamiento
A lo largo de su historia, el impuesto sobre la ventana consistía en una serie de “tallas (notches)”. Se produce una “talla” en una estructura tributaria cuando un pequeño cambio de comportamiento, como el agregado de una ventana, provoca un gran cambio en la obligación tributaria.
Las tallas son poco comunes (Slemrod 2010) y no se deben confundir con las discontinuidades o “pliegues” (kinks), que son mucho más comunes, incluso en la actualidad. Una discontinuidad en la estructura tributaria se produce cuando un pequeño cambio de comportamiento lleva a un gran cambio en la tasa tributaria marginal, pero sólo un pequeño cambio en la obligación tributaria. El impuesto sobre los ingresos en los Estados Unidos, por ejemplo, tiene varias discontinuidades. Las parejas casadas con ingresos tributables de US$17.850 a US$72.500 están en el segmento tributario marginal del 15 por ciento; las parejas con ingresos tributarios de US$72.500 a US$146.400 están en el segmento tributario marginal del 25 por ciento. Si una pareja con ingresos de US$72.500 ganara un dólar más, su tasa tributaria marginal saltaría al 25 por ciento, pero su obligación tributaria sólo aumentaría 25 centavos.
Los registros de microfilm de datos tributarios locales en el Reino Unido entre 1747 y 1830 permiten examinar de manera más sistemática el impacto del impuesto sobre la cantidad de ventanas y las tallas. Este artículo utiliza el conjunto de datos de 1747 a 1757, con información de 493 moradas en Ludlow, un pueblo comercial en Shropshire, cerca del límite con Gales. En este período, la estructura del impuesto sobre la ventana contenía 3 tallas. Durante este período, un propietario:
Los propietarios que compraban una 10a ventana, por lo tanto, pagaban un impuesto de 6 peniques sobre la 10a ventana y también sobre las 9 ventanas restantes, que antes eran libres de impuestos. O sea, el impuesto total sobre la 10a ventana era de 60 peniques, equivalente a 5 chelines. Si el impuesto sobre la ventana distorsionara las decisiones tributarias y llevara a una carga excedente, podríamos esperar que muchas casas tuvieran 9, 14 ó 19 ventanas, pero muy pocas con 10, 15 ó 20. A continuación se ensaya esta hipótesis.
Durante la primera mitad del siglo XVIII, la administración del impuesto había sido problemática, ya que los propietarios frecuentemente camuflaban o cubrían las ventanas hasta que el cobrador de impuestos se había ido, o se aprovechaban de vacíos legales o ambigüedades en el código tributario. En consecuencia, la recaudación de impuestos fue mucho menor de lo esperado. En 1747, sin embargo, el Parlamento revisó el impuesto elevando las tasas e introduciendo medidas para mejorar su administración. En particular, prohibió la práctica de cubrir y luego reabrir ventanas para evadir el impuesto; los infractores tenían que pagar una multa de 20 chelines (1 libra) por cada ventana que reabrieran sin notificarlo al inspector de impuestos (Glantz 2008).
La ley de 1747 redujo la evasión tributaria significativamente, así que los datos para los 10 años subsiguientes deberían brindar una estimación razonable de la cantidad de ventanas de una morada. Si el impuesto sobre la ventana distorsionara el comportamiento, se podría esperar un pico en la cantidad de moradas al límite de la talla, con 9, 14 ó 19 ventanas. Y esto es precisamente lo que demuestran los datos. La figura 1 es un histograma que muestra la cantidad de ventanas por vivienda de la muestra. El patrón es claro: hay aumentos bruscos en la cantidad de casas con 9, 14 ó 20 ventanas:
Los ensayos estadísticos estándar rechazan la hipótesis de que hay una cantidad igual de casas con 8, 9 ó 10 ventanas; con 13, 14 ó 15 ventanas; o con 18, 19 ó 20 ventanas. Es obvio que la gente respondió al impuesto sobre la ventana quedándose en una de las tallas para reducir al mínimo su obligación tributaria.
Los datos de una muestra de 170 casas en el período de 1761 a 1765 explican la respuesta del público a las revisiones parlamentarias del impuesto en 1761. Además de un aumento de tasas, las revisiones de 1761 ampliaron la cobertura del impuesto a casas con 8 ó 9 ventanas. En las estructuras impositivas anteriores, las casas con menos de 10 ventanas no pagaban ningún impuesto sobre la ventana. Para esta segunda muestra, en la figura 2 se observa un pico pronunciado en 7 ventanas: el 28,2 por ciento de las casas tiene 7 ventanas, pero sólo el 5,2 por ciento tiene 6 ventanas y sólo el 2,9 por ciento tiene 8 ventanas. Una vez más, es fácil rechazar la hipótesis de que había una cantidad igual de casas con 6, 7 u 8 ventanas.
En resumen, la evidencia de nuestras dos muestras demuestra claramente que había una amplia tendencia a alterar el comportamiento para reducir el pago de impuestos. La gente decidía cuántas ventanas poner, no para satisfacer sus propias preferencias, sino para no tener que pagar impuestos más altos. El impuesto sobre la ventana, en pocas palabras, generaba una “carga excedente”.
¿Cuán grande fue la carga excedente del impuesto sobre la ventana?
Como ya explicamos, el impuesto sobre la ventana era sustancial e indujo a un comportamiento generalizado para evitar el impuesto. De acuerdo a algunas técnicas estándar de análisis económico, nuestro modelo de simulación genera una estimación de lo que la gente hubiera estado dispuesta a pagar por su cantidad deseada de ventanas. El modelo captura la demanda de cada consumidor por ventanas con y sin el impuesto, la cantidad de impuestos pagada y la pérdida de bienestar al ajustar la cantidad de ventanas como respuesta al impuesto.
En la muestra de 1747 a 1757, las pérdidas estimadas de bienestar fueron muy grandes para los hogares que estaban al límite de la talla. Para ellos, la pérdida de bienestar (es decir, la carga excedente) es del 62 por ciento de los impuestos que pagaron. O sea, por cada dólar recaudado bajo nuestra versión simulada del impuesto sobre la ventana, el tributo impuso una carga o costo adicional de 62 centavos sobre dichos hogares. No es de sorprender que la carga excedente es particularmente grande para los hogares que eligieron tener 9 ventanas Uno de los criterios utilizados por los economistas para evaluar un impuesto es la carga excedente relativa a los impuestos pagados. Utilizando este criterio, un buen impuesto es aquel que recauda ingresos significativos pero produce cambios muy pequeños en las decisiones de los contribuyentes. Los consumidores que compraron 9 ventanas están por lo tanto en el peor de los casos. Estos consumidores no pagaron ningún impuesto; para ellos, entonces, toda la carga tributaria es excedente.
Para nuestra muestra completa de 1.000 hogares simulados, la carga excedente como fracción de los impuestos pagados es de alrededor del 14 por ciento. Por lo tanto, por cada dólar recaudado por el impuesto sobre la ventana, nuestra simulación sugiere la existencia de un costo adicional de 14 centavos para los contribuyentes como resultado de la distorsión en sus decisiones.
Algunos comentarios para concluir
El impuesto sobre la ventana representa un caso muy claro y transparente de carga excedente: un tributo que impuso costos altos sobre los contribuyentes además de sus obligaciones tributarias, debido a los ajustes de comportamiento que deben realizar para evitar el impuesto. Pero, como se mencionó anteriormente, los impuestos modernos sobre la propiedad también crean una carga excedente, si bien las consecuencias son menos drásticas que en el caso del impuesto sobre la ventana.
Es importante considerar este tema al diseñar un sistema tributario. Lo ideal, en principio, sería un impuesto neutral que incremente los ingresos deseados pero no distorsione el comportamiento del contribuyente creando cargas adicionales. Dicho impuesto es un tributo puro sobre el valor del suelo, gravado sobre el valor del suelo de una propiedad, es decir su valor sin mejoras. Por lo tanto, el valor de tasación del suelo (y por lo tanto la obligación tributaria del propietario) es completamente independiente de las decisiones efectuadas por el propietario de la parcela. A diferencia del impuesto sobre la ventana, que brinda un ejemplo convincente de los costos adicionales que surgen cuando la obligación tributaria depende del comportamiento del dueño de la propiedad, un impuesto sobre el valor del suelo no crea ningún incentivo de comportamiento para evadir su pago.
Sobre los autores
Wallace E. Oates es profesor universitario distinguido de Economía, emérito, de la Universidad de Maryland, y fellow universitario en Resources for the Future.
Robert M. Schwab es profesor de Economía en la Universidad de Maryland.
Recursos
Binney, J. E. D. 1958. British Public Finance and Administration, 1774–92. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Blinder, Alan S., y Harvey S. Rosen. 1985. “Notches.” American Economic Review 78 (Septiembre): 736–747.
Dickens, Charles. 1850. Household Words. Vol. 1. London: Bradbury and Evans.
Douglas, Roy. 1999. Taxation in Britain since 1660. London: MacMillan.
Dowell, Stephen. 1884. A History of Taxation and Taxes in England from the Earliest Times to the Present Day. Vols. 2 and 3. London: Frank Cass & Co.
Fielding, Henry. 1975. The History of Tom Jones, A Foundling. Wesley University Press.
George, M. Dorothy. 1926. London Life in the XVIIIth century. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.
Glantz, Andrew E. 2008. “A Tax on Light and Air: Impact of the Window Duty on Tax Administration and Architecture.” Penn History Review 1696–1851 15 (2): 1–23.
Guthrie, Thomas. 1867. “How to Get Rid of an Enemy.” The Sunday Magazine.
HCD (House of Commons Debates). 5 mayo 1819. Vol. 40 cc 126–148. “Motion for the Repeal of the Window Tax in Ireland.”
HCD. 24 February 1848. Vol. 96 cc 1259–1297. “Lowest Classes Under Assessment.”
HCD. 9 April 1850. Vol. 110 cc 68–99. “Window Tax.”
Kennedy, William. 1913. English Taxation, 1640–1799. London: G. Bell and Sons, Ltd.
Marshall, Alfred. 1948. Principles of Economics, 8th edition. New York: Macmillan.
Neary, J. Peter, y Kevin S. W. Roberts. 1980. “The Theory of Household Behaviour under Rationing.” European Economic Review 13 (Enero): 25–42.
Sallee, James M., y Joel Slemrod. “Car Notches: Strategic Automaker Responses to Fuel Economy Policy,” NBER Working Paper #16604, 2010. http://www.nber.org/papers/w16604.pdf.
Sinclair, Sir John. 1804. The History of the Public Revenue of the British Empire. London: Strahan and Preston.
Slemrod, Joel. 2010. “Buenas Notches: Lines and Notches in Tax System Design.” Unpublished working paper. http://webuser.bus.umich.edu/jslemrod/pdf/Buenas%20Notches%20090210.pdf.
Smith, Adam. 1937. The Wealth of Nations. New York: Random House.
Walpole, Spencer. 1912. A History of England from the Conclusion of the Great War in 1815. Vol. 5. London: Longmans, Green, and Company.
Weitzman, Martin L. “Prices and Quantities.” Review of Economic Studies 41: 477–491.